Skip to main content

Full text of "The "Law of the Falling Tendency of the Rate of Profit": It's Place in the Marxist Theoretical System and Relevance to the US Economy"

See other formats


64-5421 

MAGE, Shane Henry, 1933- 
THE "LAW OF THE FALLING TENDENCY OF 
THE RATE OF PROFIT": ITS PLACE IN THE 
MARXIAN THEORETICAL SYSTEM AND RELE- 
VANCE TO THE U.S. ECONOMY. 

Columbia University, Ph.D., 1963 
Economics, theory 

University Microfilms, Inc., Ann Arbor, Michigan 



TEE "IA¥ OF TEE FALUWG TENDENCY OP THE RATE OP PROFIT": 
ITS PIACE IN THE MARXIAN THEORETICAL SYSTEM AND REIEVANCE 

TO THE U,S, ECONOMY 



by 
Shane Hage 



Submitted in partial fulfil3jnent 

of the requirements for the degree of 

Doctor of Philosophy 

in the Faculty of Political Science 

Columbia University 

1963 



ABSTRACT 
THE "LAW OP THE PALLING TEI\IDENCY OP THE RATE OP 
PROPIT" : ITS PLACE IN THE MARXIAN THEORETICAL 
SYSTEM AND RELEVANCE TO THE U.Se ECONOIvIY 

by 

Shane Mage 

The concept of a falling rate of profit occupies 
a crucial position in Marx's theory of economic develop- 
ment: it is, he declared J the economic mechanism whereby 
capitalism ultimately blocks its own growth and thus proves 
that it must give way to a higher social order. 

This "law" has in the past been criticized on .two 
main grounds: It was alleged that Marx's theoretical 
derivation of a falling tendency of the rate of profit 
from a rising tendency of the "organic composition of 
capital" (the capital -labor ratio) fails to show why the 
rate of profit cannot permanently be maintained through a 
rising tendency of the "rate of exploitation" (the relative 
share of the national income going to capital) and why the 
organic composition of capital should itself tend to 
increase. It was argued, moreover, that the predictions of 
a falling rate of profit, and especially of a rising 
organic composition of capital, as formulated by Marx, have 
not been borne out by empirical data from the U.S. economy. 

The present study tests Marx's "law" both on 
theoretical and empirical grounds. 



The theoretical discussion involves stating or 
restating the basic categories of Marx's system in a way 
which establishes both their coherence with each other and 
their identifiability to empirically knowable economic 
magnitudes o This analysis involves examination of: (a) 
Marx's implicit and explicit treatment of certain contro- 
versial bvit vital questions, such as the predicted 
historical tendency of the real wage and the definition and 
treatment of "unproductive" labor; (b) Similarities and 
differences between Marxian and non-Marxian treatments of 
the central topic; (c) The inter-relationships among the 
various sections of the Marxian system* 

It is argued in conclusion that the "law of the 
falling tendency of the rate of profit" has theoretical 
validity both as a vital part of Marx's model of economic 
development under capitalism and as a logically correct 
and necessary deduction from the basic premises of the 
Marxian s3''stemo 

The empirical test of the "law" covered the U.S. 
non-farm private business economy for the period 1900-1960o 
All computations were made twice, on the basis of two 
different systems of measurement: (a) Capital stock and 
capital consumption expressed for each year in current 
dollars through deflation of original cost; (b) Capital 
stock and capital con3^amption expressed throughout in 



terms of the basic quantitative unit of the Marxian system, 
the hour of "socially necessary labor." 

The data indicate that the Marxian rate of profit 
for the U.So, \Tfhether calculated on a labor-unit or 
current-dollar basis, has fallen drastically over the past 
sixty years, and that the organic composition of capital 
has simultaneously increased, though not in as large a 
way. At the same time these data indicate another major 
tendency which Marx did not predict and which contradicts 
his anticipations J a substantial long-term decline in the 
rate of exploitation, sufficiently pronounced to account 
for two-thirds of the observed fall in the Marxian rate 
of profit. 

Nevertheless, despite the invalidation of certain 
major Marxian predictions, Marx is confirmed on the issues 
he regarded as decisive: the rising tendency of the 
organic composition of capital and the falling tendency 
of the rate of profit© 



11 



TABLE OP COKTEKTS 

Page 

GLOSSARY OF TERFiS kW RELATIONSHIPS . , v 

INTRODUCTION 1 

Chapter 

T. THE FUroAJffilWAL CATEGORIES OP THE 

MRXIAN SYSTEM 6 

II. BASIC Q,UA1\T?ITATIVE RELATIONSHIPS 36 

III. THE LAW OP THE PALLING TENDENCY OP THE 

RATE OP PRO PIT AS PRESEMED BY IvIARX 81 

TV. COMPARISON OP MAPJCIAN AND I^ION-MARXIAN 

TPIEDRIES OP A PALLING RATE OP PRO PIT Ill 

V . THEOPlETICAL CRITICISillS OP THE UM 140 

VI. CALCULATION OP THE Iv!ARXIAN RATE OP PRO PIT, 
RATE OP SURPLUS -VALUE, AND ORGASTIC 
COMPOSITION OP CAPITAL: THE UNITED 
STATES, 1900-1960, (CURPiEIW DOLLARS) 161 

VII. CALCULATION OP THE MAPXCAN RATE OP PROFIT, 
RATE OP SURPLUS -VALUE, ORGANIC COMPO- 
SITION OP CAPITAL, Al© NET PRODUCTIVITY 
OP LABOR: THE UI^TED STATES, 1900- 
1960, (LABOR-VALUE UNITS ) 196 

VIII. CONCLUSIONS <■ 220 

Appendices 

A. ANALYSIS OP THE BORTiaB'lICZ-SV/'EEZY 
CRITICISM OP IviAPJC'S SOLUTION TO THE 
"TRANSFORMATION PROBLEM" 233 

B. TABLES SUPPLEI'ffilWARY TO CHAPTER VI 246 

C . TABLES SUPPLEMENTARY TO CHAPTER VII 261 

D . TABLES SUPPLEMENTARY TO CHAPTER VIII 266 

BIBLIOGRAPFY , 276 



Ill 



LIST OP ILLUSTRATIONS 

Page 

Chart 

Vl-le Rate of Profit and Organic 

Composition of Capital, 1900-1960, 

(Current Dollar Basis) ..co o.o IVS 

VI-2o Rate of Profit and Rate of 
Surplus -Value, 1900-1960, 
(Current Dollar Basis ) » » o « o • 1"5 

VII-1. Rate of Profit and Organic 

Composition of Capital, 1900-1960, 

(Labor-Unit Basis) o .......*.. ...» 204 

VII-2, Rate of Profit and Rate of 
Surplus -Value, 1900-1960, 
(Labor-Unit Basis) «..o...». o 205 

VII-3e Organic Composition of Capital, 

Selected Years, 1900-1960 » ».. 206 

VII-4. Labor Productivity and Organic 

Composition of Capital, Selected 

Years, 1900-1960 »• 207 

D=l. Expanded (Gross of Taxes) and 
Actual (Net of Taxes) Rates of 
Profit and Surplus -Value, 1900-1960, 

(Labor-Unit Basis ) oeeo.eoee.e.e.o. »«••.•»•» '^ '^ 

D-2. Expanded (Gross of Taxes) and 
Actual (Net of Taxes) Rates of 
Profit, Peacetime Peak Years 
1905-1960, (Labor-Unit Basis) oeee<.«o 275 



LIST OF TABLES 

Table 

VI-1. Fundamental Ratios, 1900-1960, 

(Current Dollar Basis) o »•'» ^^'^ 

VII-l.o Fundamental Ratios, 1900-1960, 

(Labor -Unit Basis) ....« o... 208 

B-I. Price Index Used in 

Ciorrent Dollar Computations ««***•»«« »» ^-i 



iv 



Table -Page 

B-IIo Capital Stock, 1900-1960, 

(Current Dollar Basis) *o.*eao«*e» so. 248 

B-IIIo Capital Consumption, 1900-1960, 

(Current Dollar Basis) o 250 

B-IVs Corporate Gross Surplus -Value, 1900- 

1960, (Ciirrent Dollar Basis) 252 

B-Vo Unincorporated Business Gross Surplus- 
Value, 1900-1960, (Current 
Dollar Basis ) . . . <, ^ « . <, . o 254 

B-VIe Pre -Tax, Gross, and Net 

Surplus -Value, 1900-1960, 
(Ciu'rent Dollar Basis) .««<>•«•..... 256 

B-VII, Gross and Net Variable- 
Capital, 1900-1960,^ 
(Current Dollar Basis) s.eseo*ao*«*«o<>**»*»* 258 

C-Io Man-hours of Productive 

Labor, 1900-1960 o.... 262 

C-II. Capital Stock, Capital Consumption, 
and Labor Content of the Current 
Dollar, 1900-1960, (Labor- 
Unit Basis) • 264 

D-I. Productivity and Wage 

Indexes, 1900-1960 o.^ » « 267 

D-IIo Rates of Increase of Net- 
Productivity and Hourly Roal-ViTages »»..*..•• 269 

D-III. Capitalist Sector Gross Product, 1900- 

1960, (Current Dollar Basis) «•« o.ooo 270 

D-r/. Expanded (Gross of Taxes) Rates of 

Profit and Surplus -Value, 1900-1960, 

(Labor=Unit Basis ) »ss5o. •»».••••••»••»•«••• 272 



GLOSSARY OF TER11S kW RELATIONSHIPS 

Value: The value of the product of a capitalistic 
economy is a term used by Marx in two senses; net value 
and gross value * 

Ho) Wet Value (Y) : The net value of the annual 
product is determined by the input of productive labor 
required for its production, defined quantitatively as the 
niimber of hours worked by production and production- 
related workers. The flow of net value is identical to the 
sum of the following two flows : 

- Variable Capital (v) : the wage-cost of 
production and production-related labor input. 

- S-ur plus -value (s) : total non-labor factor net 
income o 

Y s v+s 



bo) gross Value (P) : The ' gross value cT -the 
annual product is the sum of its net value plus an 
additional flow: 

- Constant Capital (c) : the sum of overhead costs 
(exclusive of property compensation) and capital con- 
sumption, (N.B. Despite its appelation, this must always 
be recognized as a flow*) 

P s Y+-C 

Monetary flows can be converted into value flows 
through the implicit value -content of the price iinit given 
by the ratio of the net value (Y) to the money net income 



vi 



of productive laborers and proprietors of other factors 
of production. 

Capital Stock (C ) : Capital is the value, net of 
depreciation, of the stock of privately owned productive 
resources used by capitalistic enterprises o 

Productivity of Labor ? Like value, labor- 
productivity has both a p:ross and a net sense; 

^•) Gross Productivity : Gross labor-productivity 
is given by total real output per unit of productive - 
labor inputs 

be) Net Productivity of Labor (IT) ; The net 
productivity of labor is the ratio of the real income of 
productive laborers and proprietors of other factors of 
production to productive-labor input. The net productivity 
of labor is equal to its gross productivity multiplied by 
the ratio of net value to gross value. 

Organic Composition of Ca pital (Q) : The organic 
composition of capital signifies capital per worker - i.e., 
the ratio between the capital stock and productive-labor 
input o Q = - The iroinerical value of this quantity depends 

on the time period over which the flow Y is measured, and 
can be thought of as the number of production-periods em- 
bodied in the capital stock. This ratio, which is expressed 
in units of labor-value, ultimately, according to Marx, re- 
flects the technologically determined ratio of real capital 
(in "physical" units) to labor input (which latter ratio is 
termed by Marx the "technical composition of capital,") 



Vll 



Rate of Surplus -Value (sM ; The rate of surplus - 

value is the ratio between the flows surplus -value and 

variable capital, s ' = £ This ratio is determined by 

V 

the ratio of the net productivity of labor to the real wage, 
f±l ( = 1 -V - _ i-Vs») . Given the total number of*^ hours of 
productive labor performed, the rate of surplus -value de- 
termines the quantity of surplus -value : s=:Y-v=:Y--^ 

- — r" = Y (-1! — ) 



The Rate of Profit (^J.) : The Marxian rate of 

profit is the average net rate of return on investment in 

capitalistic enterprises; the ratio of surplus-value to the 

capital stock, p' - £ This rate is determined by the 

C 

relationship between the rate of surplus-value and the 

organic composition of capital: 

s _ ^^1+ s'^ s\ 



C " YQ - Q(l-ts') 

Falling Tendency of the Rate of Profit ; The incre- 
mental rate of profit, ^, (equivalent to the marginal 
efficiency of investment,) is the increase in aggregate 
property income per additional unit of net investment e Marx 
contends that all net investment tends to augment capital 
per man. If the rate of surplus -value is fixed (i.e., if 
productivity and the real wage change in the same proportion) 
the accumulation of capital must therefore produce a falling 
rate of profit, since a£l -. sj 



INTRODUCTION 

The orthodox economists have been much 
preoccupied with elegant elaborations 
of minor problems, which distract the 
attention of their pupils from the 
uncongenial realities of the modern 
world, and the development of abstract 
argument has run far ahead of any 
possibility of empirical verification. 
Mars^s Intellectual tools are far cruder, 
but his sense of reality ie far stronger, 
and his argument tovrers above their in- 
tricate conatruotions in rough and gloomy 
grandeur. n 

Joan Robinson, An Essay on Marxian Economics e' 

The "law of the failing tendency of the rate 
of profit" occupies a decisive position in the theoretical 
structure developed, primarily in the three volumes of 
Capital a by Karl I-Iarx« 

For Marx the crucial character of this "law" is 

a consequence of the central proposition of "historical 

roaterialiam'" « that every socio-economic system oomes 

into being in order to further the development of the 

productive forces, and is replaced by a different and 

higher system oniv when it ceases to be able to fulfill 

this taska i 

Kc social order ever disappears before 
all the productive forces, for which 
there is robm in it, have been developed. 



P, 2, 



and new hleher relations or production never 
appear before the material conditions of 
their existence have matured in the vomb 
of the old society."^ 

Marx and Engels characterized their social program 

as scientific socialism because it vas based, not on a 

moral criticism of capitalism, but on what they claimed 

to be the actual laws governing capitalist development: 

. . . large scale industry, as it develops 
more fully, comes into conflict with the 
barriers within which the capitalist mode 
of production holds it confined. , . . Modern 
socialism is nothing but the reflex in thought 
of this actual conflict.^ 

The falling tendency of the profit-rate, accord- 
ing to Marx is the actual economic mechanism whereby a 
capitalist economy ultimately blocks its own growth and 
thereby proves that it must give way to a higher order: 

The barrier of the capitalist mode of production 
becomes apparent: 

1. In the fact that the development of the 
productive power of labor creates in the falling 
rate of profit a law which turns into an 
antagonism of this mode of production at a 
certain point and requires for its defeat 
periodic crises. 

2. In the fact that the expansion or con- 
traction of production is determined . . . - - • 
by profit and by the proportion of this 
profit to the employed capital, thus by a 
definite rate of profit, rather than the 
relation of production to social requirements, 
i.e., to the requirements of socially developed 
human beings. It is for this reason that the 



1. Karl Marx, Critique of Political Economy (New York, 
1904), p. 12. 

2. Pried rich Engels, Antl-Duliring: (New York, 1939) ^ p. 293. 



capitalist mode of production meets with 
barriers at a certain expanded stage of 
production which, from the other point of 
view, would be altogether inadequate. It 
comes to a standstill at a point determined 
by the production and realization of profit, 
not by the satisfaction of social needs. 



The rate of profit is the motive power of 
capitalist production, and things are pro- 
duced only so long as they can be produced 
with a profit. Hence the concern of the 
English economists over the decline of the 
rate of profit. That the bare possibility 
of such a thing should worry Ricardo, shows 
his profound understanding of the conditions 
of capitalist production. The reproach moved 
against him, that he is unconcerned about 
"human beings" and has an eye solely for the 
development of the productive forces, whatever 
the cost in human beings and capital- v al ues - 
it is precisely that which is the most im- 
portant thine: aboutu.hlm. Development of the 
productive forces of social labor is the his- 
torical task and justification of capital. 
It is precisely in this way that it uncon- 
sciously creates the material requirements of 
a higher mode of production. What worries 
Ricardo is the fact that the rate of profit, 
the stimulating principle of capitalist pro- 
duction, the fundamental premise and driving 
force of accumulation, should be endangered by 
the develo-oment of production itself. And 
here the quantitative proportion, means every- 
thing. There is, indeed, something deeper be- 
hind it, of which he is only vaguely aware. 
It is here demonstrated in a pui-el^r economic 
way, i.e., from the bourgeois poin-6. of view, 
within the limitations of capitalist under- 
standing, from the standpoint of capitalist 
production itself, that it has a barrier, 
that it is relative, that it is not an ab- 
solute, but only a historical mode of produc- 
tion corresponding to a definite and limited 
epoch in the development of the material 



conditions of production.-^ 

The validity of the "law of the falling tendency 
of the rate of profit" is thus a question of the highest 
interest for modern economists. The problem ¥ith which 
Marx was most concerned, the pattern of economic growth 
under a capitalist form of social organization, has in 
the past generation become the foremost concern of 
Western economic theory and practice, and "The Lagging 
U.S. Growth Rate" is at this moment not only a subject 
for discussion among academic economists^ "but even a 
commonplace of political oratory. 

Is Marx's law of the falling rate of profit rele- 
vant to our c\irrent concerns? An answer to this question 
must proceed from both the theoretical and the practical 
side. The second part of thj.s study is devoted to a con- 
frontation of Marx»s "law" with the data of 20th-Gentury 
U.S. economic development. But before Marx's theory can 
be tested by the facts of economic life it must pass a 
prior test: it must be shown to be a correct and neces- 
sary derivation from the basic premises postulated by 



1. Karl Marx, Capital (Chicago, C. Kerr and Company, 1907- 
1909), III, "^OS-SOS. All subsequent citations of the 
English translation of Capital will refer to the Kerr 
edition. The translations have sometimes been revised in 
minor respects in light of the original text and the recent 
English translation of Volumes II and III (Moscow, 1957 and 
1959) . 

2. A symposium with this title was held at the I96I con- 
vention of the American Economic Association. 



Marx, and it must be shomi to refer to economic reality 
m such a way that its predictions can he refuted hy the 
facts. 

The first part of this study, accordingly, is 
devoted to an analysis of the derivation and meaning of 
the "law," and an examination of its validity in the 
light of the major theoretical criticisms that have been 
brought against it. 

In the course of this analysis it has continually 
been necessary to "interpret" Marx: i.e., to attempt re- 
statement of his theories in a way that is not merely 
consistent with his fundamental approach but above all 
makes them meaningful in the context of modern economics 
and of the contemporary economic system. My criterion 
in this has not been exegesis but theoretical clarifica- 
tion in the context of an empirical reality, and where 
Marx is ambiguous or even contradictory I have sought to 
interpret his meaning in as realistic a way as possible. 
For this procedure I need offer no apology beyond the 
words of Marx himself: 

The question whether objective truth is an 
attribute of human thought - is not a theo- 
retical but a practical question. Man must 
prove the truth, i.e., the reality and power, 
the "this-sidedness" of his thinking in prac- 
tice. The dispute over the reality or non- 
reality of thinking that is isolated from 
practice is a purely scholastic question, ■'• 



1. Marx, Theses on Feuerbach . Thesis II, in Karl Marx and 
Friedrich Engels, The German Ideolog:y (New York, 19^7), 
p. 197. 



CHAPTER I 
THE FUNDAMENTAL CATEGORIES OF THE MARXIAN SYSTEM 

In the preface to the first edition of Das 
Ka-pital Marx stated his essential purpose in these words: 
"It is the ultimate aim of this work to lay bare the 
economic law of motion of modern society." He sought to 
formulate a systematic and coherent scientific view of the 
historical path of development of the capitalist economic 
system from its origins to its hoped-for replacement hy a 
socialist form of economic organization. 

Marx's endeavor to determine "economic law" im- 
posed on him the requirement that he carry out his project 
in terms of economics. But his economic theory cannot be 
understood exclusively within the confines of the economics 
of capitalism. Its basis is a view of human nature and of 
the historical growth of humanity, a view whose scope far 
transcends analysis of the specifically capitalist econom- 
ic system. 

Human progress, according to Marx, consists in the 
increase of man's power over natiire. This power is made 
effective through the characteristically human process of 
labor: the social organization of human beings to co- 



1. Capital. I, 14. 



operate in the control and exploitation of the nat-ural en- 
vironment, to produce . Production, from the very dawn of 
humanity, is carried on "by means of tools: 

No sooner does labor undergo the least 
development than it requires specially pre- 
pared instruments. . . . The use and fabri- 
cation of instruments of labor, although 
existing in the germ among certain species 
of animals, is specifically characteristic 
of the human labor -process, and Franklin 
therefore defines man as a tool- making 
animal.^ 

These tools, and the techniques corresponding to 

them, constitute, with nature, the productive forces 

available to mankind at every given moment. They form 

X 

the basis for the mode of production, the social organi- 
zation of the labor-process, which in turn determines the 
total structure of the society: 

In the social production which men carry 
on they enter into definite relations that are 
indispensable and independent of their will; 
these relations of production correspond to a 
definite stage of development of their material 
powers of production. The sum total of these 
relations of production constitutes the economic 
structure of society - the real foundation, on 
which rise legal and political superstructures 
and to which correspond definite forms of social 
consciousness. The mode of production in material 
life determines the general character of the 
social, sniritual, and political processes of 
life. 2 

Capitalist society is a historically determined 

form of human society in general, and thus its central 



1. Capital . I, 200. 

2. Karl Marx, Critique of . Political Economy (New York: 
1904), p. 11; hereafter cited as Critique . 



8 



featijre, in the historical-materialist view, is its social 
organization of the labor -process. But whereas, in pre- 
vious forms of society, "the social relations between in- 
dividuals in the performance of their labor appear at all 
events as their own mutual personal relations," under 
capitalism these relationships are "disguised under the 
shape of social relations between the products of labor." 
The task of economics, according to Marx, is to penetrate 
this disguise and show how "the vrealth of society [which] 
under the capitalist system presents itself as an immense 
accumulation of commodities" in its essential reality 
expresses and is determined by the actual social relation- 
ships among human beings. 

Since these basic social relationships appear as 
exchange relationships, relationships through which every 
commodity is valued in terms of all others by means of its 
money price, Marx takes the problem of " value " as his point 
of depart-are. This problem was defined by Marx as the 
relationship betwean the e xchange -process typical of a 
capitalist society and the labor -process which he regards 
as the kernel of all human societies: 

even if there were no chapter on value in my 
book, the analysis of the real relationships 
which I give would contain the proof and 
demonstration of the real value relation 
the mass of products corresponding to the 



e 3 e 



1. Capital . I, 89. 

2. Critique , p. 19. 



different needs require different and 
quantitatively determined masses of the 
total labor of society. That this neces- 
sity of distributing social labor in 
definite proportions cannot be done away 
with by the particular for m of social pro- 
duction, but can only change the form it 
assumes , is self -evident. No natural laws 
can be done away with. \lha.t can change, 
in changing historical circumstances, is 
the form in which these laws operate. And 
the form in which this proportional divi- 
sion of labor operates, in a state of so- 
ciety where the interconnection of social 
labor is manifested in the private exchang e 
of the individual products of labor, is 
precisely the exchange -value of these pro- 
ducts. The science consists precisely in 
working out how the law of value operates.-^ 

Marx's response to this problem, the "labor theory 
of value," starts with the postulate that the value of a 
commodity consists of the portion of social labor al- 
located by society to its production. As Joan Robinson 
correctly remarks, this conception of value "is purely a 
matter of definition. The value of a commodity consists 
of the labor -time required to produce it, including the 
labor-time required by subsidiary commodities which enter 
into its production." 

That "value" in this sense is something quite dif- 
ferent from "utility" or "use-value" is obvious, Marx, 
in declaring that to be a commodity every commodity must 
both "satisfy human wants" and be a "product of labor," 



1. Karl Marx, Letter of II/7/I868 to Dr. Kugelman?i,ln 
Karl Marx and Priedrich Engels, Selected Correspondence 

(New York, 193^), p. 246. " 

2. Joan Robinson, An Essay on Marxian Economics (London, 
1952), p. 13. 



10 



merely repeats the basic distinction established by Smith 
and RicardOe 

Vftiat is ne-w in Marx's use of the term ''value" is 
that he establishes a radical disjuncture between the 
category of value and that of price , insofar as these 
apply to individual commodities or groups of commodities o 
One of his sharpest criticisms of the Ricardian value 
theory is that Ricardo seeks to determine "relative 
value" on the basis of the relative quantity of labor in 
the commodities to be exchanged, 

Ricardo 's error, according to Marx, is that since 
in reality the "natural prices" at which commodities tend 
in the long run to be exchanged are governed (under com- 
petitive conditions) by "prices of production which are 
not directly determined by the values of the commodities 
o e . he should therefore hcive said: These average prices 
of production are different from the values of the com- 
modities. Instead of this he concludes that they are 
identical • . . o"""- Thus Ricardo finds himself driven 
toward an admission "that values are themselves determined 
by influences independent of labor timeo" 

All Individual money relationships, in Marx's 
view, are necessarily characterized by this difference 
between price and value ; 



lo Karl Marx, Theories of Surplus Value (New York, 1952), 
po 213, hereafter cited as Theories . 

2o Ibid., p. 233e 



11 



Magnitude of value expresses a relation of 
social production, it expresses the connection 
that necessarily exists between a certain 
article and the portion of the total labor - 
time of society required to produce it. As 
soon as magnitude of value is converted into 
price, the above necessary relation takes the 
shape of a more or less accidental exchange - 
ratio between a single commodity and another, 
the money commodity. . . . The possibility, 
therefore, of quantitative incongruity between 
price and magnitude of value, or the deviation 
of the former from the latter, is inherent in 
the price form itself. This is no defect, but, 
on the contrary, admirably adapts the price 
form to a mode of production whose inherent laws 
impose themselves only as the mean of apparently 
lawless irregularities that compensate one 
another. •'• 

The commodity, then, taken in itself, has two op- 
posite characteristics: utility and price, use -value and 
ex change -value . In Marx's Hegelian terminology the com- 
modity's value constitutes the "identity" of these "opposites" 
because as value it no longer appears as a thing in itself 
but is now apprehended as the product of a definite amount 
of social labor, (in the Hegelian dialectic onposites are 
not to be thought of as the terms of a logical contradiction 
or paradox but as poles of a dynamic logical -process . In 
the case of the commodity, abstract utility, usefulness as 
such, is the fundamental category, the initial pole. The 
coat is produced as a coat. But when it enters the market 
as a commodity offered for sale its seller regards it simply 
as a sum of money to be realized by the sale - its utility 



1. Capital . I, 11^. 



12 



has been negated, its form changed from use-value to ex- 
change-value, though it remains a real coat all the time. 
When it is bought by the final consumer it becomes an ob- 
ject of utility again and loses its commodity form. Thus, 
sale to the user is "negation of negation." This process 
has given the category of use -value a new meaning, raised 
it to a higher level than the original "utility" that was 
abstracted from in the offer of the c-iat for sale. The 
social process of sale has not merely provided the purchaser 
vith a useful article - it has also influenced the alloca- 
tion of social resources to the production of coats, and 
thereby helped to determine the value of the subsequent 
output of coats. Thus the Marxian category of value , despite 
the opinion of a number of commentators,-^ is not derived 
through abstraction from use -value but on th© contrary in- 
volves use-value at least equally vith exchange -value. As 
Engels'vrote (in 18431 ) " Value is the relation of -production 
costs to utility ."^ 



1. Thus Hilferding wrote: "the natural (l) aspect of the 
commodity, its use- value, lies outside the domain of politi- 
cal economy," (B6hm-Bawerk ' s Criticism of Marx LNew York, 
1949], p. 130). And Sweezy repeats: ''Marx excluded use-value 
(or, as it would now be called, 'utility') from the field of 
investigation of political economy." (Sweezy, Theory of 
Capitalist Development [New York, 1942], p. 26). The in- 
compatibility of these interpretations with Marx's actual 
doctrine is thoroughly demonstrated in the essay by R. Rosdolsky, 
"Der Gebrauchswert bei Karl Marx, Elne Kritik der Bisherlgen 
Marx-Interpretation," Kvklos . XII, 29-53. 

2. Friedrich Engels, Outlines of a Critique of Political 
Economy , in Karl Marx, Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts 
of 1844 (Moscow, 1959), p. 186. 



Viewed pragmatically, the establishment of value 
as a "higher" category than price reflects a division of 
the subject matter of economics into different sets of 
problems, for each of which different analytic tools are 
required, 

Marx, as ve have seen, recognizes the market as 
the mechanism whereby society allocates its productive 
resources among alternative uses. The analysis of exchange - 
value is aimed at comprehending a price system whose function 
is "to bring that quantity of commodities on the market 
which social requirements demand; in other words, that 
quantity of commodities whose market-value society can pay."-"- 

These problems of short-run resoTorce allocation, 
however, are not Marx's main concern. True, Chapter X of 
the Third Volume of Das Kapital. "Market Prices and Market 
Values," with its declaration that "the market-value is 
always regulated by the commodity produced under the least 
favorable circumstances, if the supply is too small, and by 
the commodity produced under the most favorable conditions, 
if the supply is too large, "^ leaves the door wide open for 
development of a marginal-cost price theory. But Marx him- 
self did not formulate any such theory. 

For Marx's central purpose, elucidation of "the 



1, Capital . Ill, 213. 

2. Ibid .. Ill, 218. 



14 



economic law of motion of modern society," he needed in-- 
struments of analysis appropriate to the study of long- 
term economic growth and of the division of the social 
product among the basic social classes. In order to 
measure and compare economic magnitudes over time he needed 
to reduce relative prices, expressed in money, to a dimension 
which could make them measurable in terms of a unit of 
measure which would not itself vary over time o 

As the unit of measure in which "social labor" is 
to be quantified Marx postulates the unit of duration: 
"The quantity of lahor is measured by its duration, and 
labor-time finds its standard in weeks, days, and hours." 
Marx thus defines value as a quantity of labor-time » 

This definition of value does not start from the 
"surface phenomena" of commodity-exchange: its starting 
point is the labor-process in society as a whole. The Marxian 
concept of value , accordingly, has meaning and can be under- 
stood only in social terms. The primary category from which 
all other economic quanta are derived by Marx is the aggre- 
gate labor at the disposal of society. Viewed from the 
angle of the individual producer, "the labor-time of a single 
individual is directly expressed in exchange -value as uni- 
versal labor-time, and this universal character of individual 
labor is the manifestation of its social character." Sim- 



1. Capital , I, 45. 

2o -Marx, Critique , p. 26« 



15 



llarly-j starting from the relative ex change -value of oom- 
modities in terms of each other, "their relativity by no 
means consists only in the ratio in which they exchange for 
each other, but in the ratio of all of them to this social 
labor vhich is their substance."-^ 

"Social labor" consists in reality of the labor of 
a vast number of different individuals, producing different 
things with different uses» In this sense, as being always 
at bottom the unique labor of ?. definite individual under 
definite social conditions producing an object with a 
definite utility, Marx calls it "concrete labor." 

The formulation of an abstract unit of measxjre in 
terms of labor-time requires abstraction from these dif- 
ferences. In Hegelian terms, the category forming the 
ground of the unit of measure consists of the "identity" 
of the "opposites" abstract labor and concrete labor. 
"Wliat this means is that the working- time of every indivi- 
dual is viewed as a fraction of the total working time of 
society. 

Proceeding from this aggregate, Marx defines the 
way in which labor -time can be made into an objective 
unit of measure: the work of different individuals is 
to be expressed as "socially necessary labor-time." As 
Marx states it: 



1. Marx, Theories , p. 210. 



16 



The total labor-power of society, which is 
emhodled in the sum total of the values of 
all commodities produced by that society, 
counts here as one homogeneous mass of human 
labor -power, composed though it be of in- 
numeralDle individual units. Each of these 
units is the same as any other, so far as 
it has the character of the average labor - 
power of society, and takes effect as such; 
that is, so far as it requires for producing 
a commodity no more time than is needed on 
an average, no more than is socially necessary. 
The labor-time socially necessary is that re- 
quired to produce an article under the normal 
conditions of production and with the average 
degree of skill and intensity prevalent at 
the time. 

If qualitatively unlike, unique units of labor 

are to be quantified this must be done in a dimension 

objectively common to all of them, and all, necessarily, 

posess duration, take place in a temporal universe. This 

essential nature of Marx's category of "socially necessary 

labor- time" as a term of measiirement, is well stated by 

Naville: 

It is time that remains the foundation of this 
conception. In other words, society has at its 
disposal a given mass of labor-power and of 
labor- time, concretized in quanta having among 
themselves a certain relationship of proportion- 
ality. As a mass in activity, "abstract^' labor 
can be conceived as an energetic substance 
common to all labors. As a potential mass it 
is to be conceived as a disposable time, 
measurable in homogeneous units. But in one 
as in the other case it can be considered in 
its abstract, social form only in function of ^ 
its concrete forms. 2 



1, Capital . I, 46. 

2. Pierre Naville, De L' Alienation a la Joui ssaace (Paris, 
1957),. p. 414. 



17 



The determination of "socially necessary labor- 
time" thus Involves the transformation of a qualitatively 
heterogeneous mass of different concrete labor-powers 
into a homogeneous magnitude. The quanta of this magni- 
tude are units of the "average labor-power of society," 
Consequently individual labor-powers of differing skill 
stand in a quantitative as well as a qualitative rela- 
tionship one to another: all can be expressed in terms 
of this fundamental unit as it is manifested in the value 
of the commodities produced; i.e., in time-units of 
"simple, average, labor." 

This Quantitative relationship^ by which the 
labor of every worker differs, even if infinites imally, 
from the labor of every other, is thus defined by Marx 
as relative de\^iation from a "mean," "dsm gesellschaft- 
lichen Durchschnittsgrad von Ges chick und Intensity t der 
Arbeit."-^ 

"Simple, average, labor," in consequence, like 
all Marx's categories, is properly viewed only as a 
socially determined magnitude. It is the labor, not of 
some standard, "unskilled," worker, but of the averae;e 
worker, the laborer working with " the average degree of 
skill and intensity ." An hour of the labor of this 
"average" worker is the measure of "abstract labor," and 



1. Karl Marx, Das Kapital (Wien, 1933-193^),- I, 5> cited 
in translation, supra , p. l5o 



18 



thus the basic quantitative unit of the entire Marxian 
system . 

All the aspects of concrete labor must vary 
continually, but this unit of abstract labor Is In- 
variant to time, no matter how vastly the productivity 
of concrete labor may increase: "However then produc- 
tive pover may vary, the same labor, exercised during 
equal periods of time, always yields equal amounts of 
value. ""^ Historic changes in "the average degree of 
skill and Intensity" itself are to be taken into account 
as a factor Increasing the -productivity of labor and 
consequently do not touch the unit of measure: 

The value of a commodity would remain constant 
if the labor-time required for its production 
remained constant. But the latter changes with 
every variation in the productiveness of labor. 
This productiveness is determined by various 
circumstances, amongst others, by the average 
amount of skill of the workmen, the state of 
science and the degree of its practical ap- 
plication, the social organization of pro- 
duction, the extent and capabilities of the 
means of production, and by physical conditions. ^ 

By defining the unit of value as the hour of 
socially necessary labor-time Marx establishes an empir- 
ically utilisable standard of measurement, based on a 
knowable quantity: the number of hours of labor performed 
by productive workers in the course of the year. The way 



1. Capital . I, 53. 

2. Ibid ., p. 47. 



19 



in which it is to Toe used depends on a further definition: 
the relationship of value to the units of money in which 
a market-economy society conducts its economic activities. 

This relationship is formulated by Marx by means 
of an identity: money is "the phenomenal form that must 
of necessity be assumed by that measure of value which 
is inananent in commodities, labor-time."^ Conversely, 
price is "value in the form of money." By definition, 
therefore, the monetary unit of a given society at a 
given time, whether it nominally consists of gold or of 
inconvertible paper, represents a definite quantity of 
value. It has a definite labor -content. 

This fundamental term, the labor -content of the 
price unit , is identically the ratio between two empirical- 
ly determinable magnitudes, the sum of prices and the sum 
of values of the commodities produced in the year. Equiv- 
alent ly, it is the ratio between the money net income of 
the laborers and capitalists and the number of hours of 
productive , labor performed in the year. 

Through this identity any economic quantity ex- 
pressed in prices of a particular year is theoretically 
convertible into value -units . Accordingly, the Marxian 
theories concerning the division of the valu e of the 
social product among the classes and the proportions 



1. Capital . I, 101. 
2= Ibid. , III, 227. 



20 



between the value nevly created and the value accumu- 
lated in the past in the form of the material pre- 
conditions of production are subject to testing on the 
basis of knowable facts. The Marxian system is thus 
capable of generating empirically refutable predictions. 

The "labor theory of value," as the basis of a 
definitional structure, cannot be considered as "true" 
or "false" in itself - its validity depends on its in- 
dispensability to the formulation of empirically valid 

theories. 

Recogni2ing its definitional nature, Joan 
Robinson directs tvo highly germane criticisms to the 
"labor theory of value": 

In the first place, she argues, "The problem of 
finding a measure of real output - a measure "which, in 
the natxire of the case, must contain a certain arbitrary 
element - is not solved by reckoning in terms of value, 
for the rate of exchange between value and output is 
constantly altering."^ 

This is true and vitally important, but as an 
ob.iection to Marx's use of labor-time as a unit of 
measurement it misses the mark. 

The essential point is that the output of a given 
period consists of commodities which inherently are both 



1. Robinson, Essay , p. 20. 



21 



exchange -values and use-values. To measure output only 
ill value terms Is to make labor -productivity a meaning- 
less notion, since the value of the commodities is iden- 
tical to the quantity of labor required for their pro- 
duction. But Marx is continually concerned with the 
nroductivity of labor - it is, in fact, his dominant 
concern, and explicitly one of the basic categories of 
his system. Since production means determinate change 
of form, and consequently requires measurement of output 
in different units from those in vhich input is measured, 
it is evident that Marx either was talking nonsense or 
that he posessed, at least implicitly, a conceptual basis 
for measurement of real output. 

The latter is clearly the case. Marx explicitly 
maintains that commodities can be aggregated in their 
character as use-values . Thus, virtually at the begin- 
ning of Volume I, he writes: 

The same change in productive power which 
increases the fruitfulness of labor and, 
in consequence, the quantity of use-values 
produced by that labor, will diminish the 
total value of this increased quantity of 
use-values, provided such change shortens 
the total labor-time necessary for their 
production.^ 



1. Of. supra . pp. 11— 12. Utility is unmeasurable only in 
its "abstract" form of "mere subjective utility" (Engels). 
The market transformation is an objective, social process. 
Through the very negation of "utility" it becomes social 
and therefore quantifiable, so that Marx continually speaks 
of the "quantity of use-values." 

2. Capital . I, 5^. 



S2 



Marx is therefore subject to justified criticism, 
not for the absence from his system of a conceptual basis 
for the measiirement of real output but for his taking 
such measurement for granted, his failiore to derive an 
explicit unit of measure of real output. 

This gap in the Marxian definitional structure 
can easily be filled in practice by means of measurement 
of output in constant prices through whatever price-index 
is judged appropriate. The theoretical problem is to 
demonstrate the coherence of this system of meas^jrement 
with the rest of Marx's basic categories. What must be 
formulated is the meaning, in Marxian terms, of a " real " 
quantity: in other vords, vhen ve meas^lre use-value in 
"constant prices" just what is it that ve are using as 
our unit of meas\Are? 

When the product of 1955 is expressed as a quan- 
tity of "1954 dollars" vhat this means is that every 
unique commodity has been assigned a second price, dif- 
■f erlng from its actual -price . But for Marx "price is 
value in the form of money," Abstraction from current 
price means abstraction from current value , which latter 
term of course is grounded on the abstract category of 
"socially necessary labor-time." The transformation of 
current to constant prices thus represents abstraction 
from abstraction, the restoration of concreteness on a 
new level. 



23 



In plain English: the products of one year are 
represented as the products of the labor of a different 
year. In proportions determined by the relative prices of 
that base year. By their expression in 195^ dollars the 
commodities of 1955 are expressed as quantities of 1954 
labor -time. But ¥hen labor- time is specified as being 
that of a definite year we have ceased to abstract from 
the social demand which determined the allocation of 
resources, hence the relative price structure, prevailing 
in that year. To measure in terms of dated labor is to 
view this labor as concrete labor. This, indeed, is pre- 
cisely what is required, since Marx defines the "concrete- 
ness" of labor as its productivity of use- value. 

The quantxim of use -value thus is to be defined as 
the hour of dated social labor -time . Its practical de- 
termination is inherently a problem of relative, not ab- 
solute, measurement, since the entire system of measure- 
ment depends on the base-year chosen. 

One can only speculate on the reasons for Marx's 
failure to specify how productivity is to be measiored. 
Perhaps, in an epoch before the technique of index-number 
construction was developed in practice, he was satisfied 
with generalized, qualitative discussions of productivity 
which do in fact provide a tolerable treatment of the 
main problems. 

In my opinion Marx avoided the problem mainly 



24 



because of what Joan Robinson calls the "arbitrary ele- 
ment" in the system of measiirement. This does not only 
involve "the index-n\amber problem," the arbitrary selec- 
tion of a base year. It is equally important that to 
Marx the pattern of needs, of effective use-values, in a 
capitalist society is itself "arbitrary," determined by 
a distribution of vealth, income, and power that he in- 
dicts as distorting real social needs, real utility, and 
which he seeks to abolish. 

In any event, measurement of real output in 
constant-price units , use -value units , is perfectly con- 
sistent with measurement of factor input, capital and 
income, in value units ^ labor -time units . The productiv- 
ity of labor, as real product per unit of labor input, is 
determinable only through the use of both systems of 
measurement simultaneously, within the Marxian framework. 

Joan Robinson's second criticism of the "labor 
theory of value" is even more crucial. Calculation in 
terms of value, she declares, is useless for Marx: "none 
of the important ideas which he expresses in terms of the 
concept of value cannot be better expressed without it.""^ 
The va lue unit is "otiose": "It has no operational con- 
tent. It is just a word." 



1. Robinson, Essay , p. 20. 

2. Joan Robinson, Economic Philosophy (Chicago, I962) , p. ^ 



25 



But is it true that use of some other unit of 
measure would more effectively produce the same testable 
theories that Marx derived through analysis in terms of 
value? Mrs, Robinson asserts this, but she does not 
demonstrate it. On the contrary - her own theoretical 
work (strongly influenced by Marx) points to the area 
where calculation in terms of value is indispensable to 
Marx's structure. 

This is the category of capital . Marx makes 
capital unambiguously measurable by defining it as the 
accumulated value invested in privately- owned means of 
production. What is the alternative? J. B. Clark defines 
capital as "a permanent fund of productive wealth , » . 
describable in terms of 'money'." He does not, however, 
specify the quanta of this "permanent fund" which is 
"invested in material things which are perpetually shift- 
ing - which come and go continually - although the fund 
abides."*- And when Joan Robinson herself, in her book 
The Accumulation of Capital , comes' face to face with this 
problem, she has to declare non possummus ; "The evalua- 
tion of a stock of capital goods is the most perplexing 
point in the whole of the analysis which we have under- 
taken. Indeed in reality it is insoluble in principle."^ 



1. J. B. Clark, The Distribution of Wealth (New York, 1902). 

2. Ibid ., p. 122e 

3. Joan Robinson, The Acciimulation of Capital (London, 
1956), p. 117. 



26 



The essential relevance of the "labor theory of 
value," its operational content, is precisely that it 
makes the problem of "evaluation of a stock of capital 
goods" soluble In -princi-ple , 

SxjTplus -Value 

The essential thing that must be understood in 

discussing Marx's analysis of the category "capital" is 

that, in his viev, capital is not a "factor of production"; 

Capital is not a thing. It is a definite 
interrelation in social production belonging 
to a definite historical formation of society. 
This interrelation expresses itself through a 
certain thing and gives to this thing a speci- 
fic social character. Capital is not the sum 
of the material and produced means of produc- 
tion. Capital means rather the means of pro- 
duction converted into capital, and means of 
production by themselves are no more capital 
than gold or silver are money in themselves. 
Capital signifies the means of production 
monopolized by a certain part of society, the 
products and material requirements of labor 
made independent of labor -pover in living 
human beings and antagonistic to them, and 
personified in capital by this antagonism, ■'■ 

There is thus a clear distinction between Capital, 

on the one hand, and the real "factors," Land and Labor, 

on the other: 

Capital is a definite form of an element of 
production belonging to a definite mode of 
production having a'definite cast. It is an 
element of production combined vith and re- 
presented by a definite social form. The 
other tvo. Land on the one hand and Labor on 



1. Capital . Ill, 947. 



27 



the other, are two elements of the real labor 
process. In their material form they are 
common to all modes of production^ they are 
the material elements of all processes of 
production, and they have nothing to do with 
the social form of productive processes, l 

In sum, for Marx the concept of capital as "factor 
of production" is an instance of "commodity-fetishism," 
of visualizing the economic process as a system of rela- 
tions among things . not of relations among people . 
Things are capital if and only if they express the 
specifically capitalist social relationship; i.e., if 
they serve the production, not of utilities or even of 
value in general, but of a specific type of value, 
surplus -value . 

Surplus-value is the capitalist form of a phenom- 
enon common to all post-primitive forms of human society: 
the formation of a social surplus above and beyond the 
needs of the direct producers as a material expression of 
surplus -labor, and the appropriation of this surplus by 
the ruling class: 

Capital did not invent surplus -labor. Wherever 
a part of society posesses a monopoly of the 
means of production the laborer, free or not 
free, must add to the working time necessary 
for his own maintenance an extra working time 
in order to produce the means of subsistence 
for the owner of the means of production, 
whether this proprietor be an Athenian aris- 
tocrat, Etruscan theocrat, Roman citizen, 
Norman baron, American slave-holder, Wallacian 



1. Capital . Ill, 949. 



28 



boyar, modern landlord - or capitalist. 

This siirplus -labor, under capitalism, takes the 

form of value , because that is the form which all labor 

must take under this mode of production: 

It is every bit as important for an under- 
standing of surplus -value, to conceive it 
as a mere congelation of surplus -labor -time, 
as nothing but objectified surplus -.lab or, as 
it is for an understanding of value in general 
to conceive it as a mere congelation of labor- 
time, as nothing but objectified labor. Only 
the mode in vhich this surplus -labor is extracted 
from the direct producer, the laborer- dif- 
ferentiates the various economic forms of 
society. 2 

Thus for Marx the decisive point in the entire 
fabric of capitalist social relationships, the point at 
vhich the objective preconditions of production manifest 
their character as capital , is the institution of vage- 
labor . the legal freedom and economic necessity for the 
individual worker to alienate to another person, during 
a defined period and for a money-price, the utilization 
of his ability to work. "The form of labor, as wage= 
labor, determines the shape of the entire process and 
the specific mode of production itself. "^ 

In form , wage- labor is an equalitarian relation- 
ship, the exchange of equivalents. For a price agreed 



1. Capital . I, 259. 

2. Ibid., p. 2^1. 

3. Ibid .. Ill, 1028. 



29 

to by both, the capitalist purchases from the worker the 
right to use his labor-power for a given period. In 
content, according to Marx, the relationship is one of 
exploitation. The value of the worker's labor-power is 
determined by the number of hours of social labor-time in 
the form of money needed to purchase the goods required to 
develop the worker's skills and maintain him and his family 
at the standard of living regarded as "normal" in the given 
society. This number of hours, as we have seen, must be^ 
less than the working -day . The difference accrues to the 
capitalist who owns the entire product of the worker's labor 
(i.e., the effects of the consumption of the labor-power 
which has been bought at its value); but for this reason it 
accrues not as a deduction, but as a new product. 

The capitalist does not steal from the worker: 
he exploits him. Consequently the relationships between 
the classes take on a specifically capitalistic, quanti- 
tatively-determined, form. That form is the ratio between 
the surplus -value produced by the worke r and the value 
paid to him for the right to utilize hi s labor-power; 
the "rate of surplus -value." It expresses the internal 
division of the working-day into a time dviring which the 
worker produces for himself his necessary means of 
subsistence and a time during which he produces for his 
employer the social surplus. 

Marx devotes Chapter XVIII of Volume I to a dis- 



30 



cussion of the correct expression for the rate of surplus - 
value. He states categorically that tMs relationship 
must be expressed only as the ratio between " surplus 
labor " and " necessary labor " (in symbols, s', the rate 
of exploitation, - i , s representing surplus -value and 

V representing value of labor-power) ^ and not the ratio 

between surplus -labor-time and the total working-day 

(-^) , even though this second formula is directly 
^ sfv ' * " 

derived from the first (_|_ z ^-~- )• 

What Marx is actually concerned with here is to 
emphasize that the basic relationship is not the 
division of a given product but the production of a 
new substance: surplus -value. The "rate of exploitation" 
is the "direct expression of the degree of self -expansion 
of capital o"-*- 

The category v in the formula - has in fact a 
dual significance, corresponding to the already analyzed 
dual character of s. As the share of the workers in the 
social product it expresses a category common to all forms 
of society. But it is also the quantitative expression 
for a section of the social capital , that section which. 



1. Capital, I, 583, 



31 



according to Marx, is alone responsible for the "self- 
expansion of capital," because, by setting labor -power 
into motion and transforming it into va lue . it leads to 
the production of surplus -value. The rate of exploita- 
tion thus expresses "the very transaction that charac- 
terizes capital, namely the exchange of variable capital 
for living labor -power and the consequent exclusion of 
the laborer from the product."-^ 

Marx consequently regards the social capital as 
made up of two components, constant capital and variable 
capital , whose qualitative difference, it should be noted 
clearly, is not based on any distinction in regard to 
their concrete physical attributes but is entirely an 
expression of the difference in their social function , 
manifested in the way in which they transfer value to the 
commodity produced. Only capital expended on living 
[productive] labor leads to the formation of surplus- 
value and so adds to the commodity a value greater than 
itself. Its value varies in the course of the reproduc- 
tion process. Machines mightily enhance the productive 
power of labor, but they are not directly productive of 
value in the Marxian view. Since by definition value 
consists of human labor-time, a thing cannot impart more 
value to its product than the value which it already 



1. Capital , I, 584. 



32 



Ui 



contains as a product of past human labor. 

That part of capital then, vhich Is represented 
by the means of production, by the rav material, 
axixiliary material, and the Instruments of labor 
does not, in the process of production, undergo 
any quantitative alteration of value. I there- 
fore call it the constant part of capital, or, 
more shortly, constant capital,. 

On the other hand that part of capital repre- 
sented by labor power does, in the process 
of production, undergo an alteration of value. 
It both reproduces the equivalent of Its ovn 
value and also produces an excess, a surplus- 
value, which may itself vary, may be more or 
less according to circumstances. This part of 
capital is continually being transformed from 
a constant into a variable magnitude. I there- 
fore call it the variable part of capital or, 
shortly, variable capital . ■*• 

Variable capital , then, is the sum of wages ex- 
pended on the purchase of labor -pover to be consumed In 
productive labor: constap .i; capital is the remainder of 
the total capital: 

The same elements of capital which, from the 
point of view of the labor process, present 
themselves respectively as the objective and 
subjective factors, as means of production 
and labor-power, present themselves, from the 
point of view of the process of creating surplus - 
value, as constant and variable capital. 2 

Summary of Chapter I 

The basic economic category in the Marxian system 
is that of value. Marx establishes a fundamental dlstlnc- 



1. Capital . I, 232. 

2. Ibid ., p. 233. 



33 



tion between value and price . The former is defined as 
the quantity of socia ll y necessary labor-time expended 
in the production of a commodity^ the latter as the 
exchange -ratio of a commodity to other commodities ex- 
pressed in money and established at a particular time 
by the market mechanism. This distinction reflects the 
difference between aggregative long-run and partial 
short-run economic analysis. Marx's main concern is 
with long-run analysis in aggregative terms. 

Marx defines money as the "phenomenal form" of 
value ; the monetary unit of a given society at a given 
time is held to represent a determinate amount of labor- 
time. This labor -content of the price ui^lt is empiri- 
cally determinable through the ratio between the aggre- 
gate value of the commodities produced by a society in a 
time period and the sum of the prices of those commodities 
It is also Identical to the number of hours of productive 
labor performed in the time period divided by the money 
net Income of the laborers and capitalists during that 
period. 

Measurement of the productivity of labor requires 
calculation of real output in another unit than that used 
to measiire factor input. Marx treats use -value (utility) 
as a quantifiable magnitude, but falls to provide an ex- 
plicit unit of measiire for real output. Measurement of 
output in constant p rices is fully in accordance with 



54 



the implicit Marxian treatment of the category of use- 
value. 

Capital is made subject to an objective standard 
of measurement by Marx's definition of it as accumulated 
past labor . Its essential nature, in Mars's view, is to 
serve as the means vhereby the class of capitalists ap- 
propriates the social siorplus -product. 

Under capitalism this surplus -product has to be 
sold on the market, and therefore takes the form of 
sTirplus- value . Surplus -value is defined as the dif- 
ference between the total niimber of hours worked by 
productive laborers in the course of the year and the 
value (the labor-content of the money) paid to them as 
wages . 

The value of the money wage is called variable 
capital by Marx because in return for this money the 
worker must perform more hours of work than his wage 
represents, and thereby add surplus -value to it. The 
ratio between surplus -value and variable capital is 
identical to this ratio of the "unpaid" to the "paid" 
portion of the working day. Marx calls this ratio the 
rate of surplus -value or rate of exploitation . 

In addition to variable capital and surplus -value 
the value of a commodity also contains value transferred 
to it through the consumption of raw materials and 
through the wear and tear (depreciation and obsolescence) 



35 



undergone by the machinery used in production. Capital 
consumed in this way merely transfers its own value to 
the product, without creating any new value. Its value, 
thus, can be said to remain constant, changing only in 
concrete outer form. Those expenses of production which 
merely transfer pre-existing value to the product are 
termed by Marx constant capital . 



36 



CHAPTER II 
BASIC QUANTITATIVE RELATIONSHIPS 

The value of the gross product , during a given 
period J of the total social capital, resolves itself 
into these three constituent parts: variable capital , 
constant capital , and surplus -value . (In symbols, 
P = c^vfrs) To each of these categories corresponds a 
section of the mass of commodities produced having a 
specific social destination. The variable capital is 
objectified in those xise -values consiamed by the class 
of productive -wage -laborers ; the constant capital in 
those use-values required to maintain intact the con- 
ditions of production and reproduction in the broadest 
sense; the surplus -value in those use -values consumed 
or invested by the class of capitalists. 

The value of the social net product , on the other 
hand, consists solely of the new value produced; namely, 
the sum of variable capital and surplus -value . The net 
product in real (constant-price) terms is therefore 
identical to the real net income of the classes of labor- 
ers and capitalists, i.e., the purchasing pover of aggre- 
gate vages and surplus -value . Consequently the produc- 
tivity of labor (computed, of course, as the index of 



37 



real production per man-hour) has two distinct senses: 
a gross productivity and a net productivity . The two 
will TDe in a stable proportion only if the share of the 
value of the gross product consisting of constant capital 
remains stable. If the percentage of constant capital 
increases, then gross productivity will grow faster than 
net productivity, and inversely. 

"c" and "v" in the foregoing identity are flow 
variables . whose value depends on the period over which 
they are computed. But, as their names indicate, each 
corresponds to a section of the total capital stock, 
which is determinable at any instant. This capital 
stock, therefore, can be defined by the identity K s C^V, 
with each /upper case/ stock variable related to its 
/Tower case/ flow counterpart, by a specific rate of 

turnover . 

The difference between these rates of turnover, 
however, is so great that Such a procedure would un= 
necessarily complicate the whole analysis . A better pro- 
cedure is to assume that the stock of variable capital 
is virtually zero, so that the capital stock is assumed 
to consist entir e ly of constant capital, i.e., K i C. 

This assumption may appear drastic, but in fact 
it is extremely realistic. Most large businesses in 
practice segregate the "variable" portion of their cir- 
culating capital in a special payroll account, whose 



38 



Tnaximum size is slightly atove the average payroll. But 
since production workers are generally paid several 
days to a week after the close of the payroll period, the 
■•'stock of variable capital" is always equalled or even 
exceeded hy the liability "wages payable," so that its 
net value is actually zero or even negative I Marx was 
quite well aware of this, when in Volume 1 (p. 62l) he 
wrote "the laborer is not paid until after he has expended 
his labor-power . , . he has produced, before it flows 
back to him in the shape of wages, the fund out of which 
he himself is paid, the variable capital." Gillman, 
in his statistical study though not in his theoretical 
exposition, correctly sets the stock of variable capital 
at zero. We will do likewise throughout this study. 

These three variables ( C , v, s. ) form the terms 
in which Marx expresses the three fundamental quantita- 
tive relationships of his system: the rate of exploita- 
tion (§.«). the organic composition of capital (Q) , and 
the rate of profit (p'). 

The Rate of Surplus -Value 

The numerical value of the rate of surplus -value, 
and therewith the quantity of surplus -value produced, is 
determined by two factors : the length of the working day 



1. Cf . Joseph Gillman, The Falling Rate of Profit (London, 
1957) I pp. ^-^''-^5- 



->■ 



39 



and the value of labor -po^er (i.e., the length of the 
"necessary" portion of the working-day). These magni- 
tudes are conceived as the average representative of 
the corresponding social aggregate. 

The labor vhich is set in motion by the 
total capital of a society, day in, day 
out, may be regai--ded as a single collective 
■working-day. If, e.g., the number of labor- 
ers is a million, and the average working- 
day of a laborer is 10 hours, the social 
•working-day consists of ten million hours . 

Similarly, 

The variable capital of a capitalist is the 
expression in money of the total value of all 
the labor povers that he employs simultan- 
eously. Its value is, therefore, equal to 
the average value of one labor -power, multi- 
plied by the number of labor-povers employed.'^ 

Any change in the rate of surplus -value must be 
the consequence of a change in one or both of these 
quantities, and therefore Marx draws a distinction be- 
tween two different methods of augmenting that rate: 

The surplus -value produced by prolongation 
of the working -day, I call absolute surplus - 
value . on the other hand, the surplus -value 
arising from the curtailment of the necessary 
labor-time, and from the corresponding altera- 
tion in the respective lengths of the two 
components of the working -day, I call relative 
surplus -value . 3 



1. Capital, I, 336. 

2. Ibid., p. 331. 

3. Ibid . 3 p. 345. 



40 



It should tie made clear that Marx uses the 
terms "absolute" and "relative" surplus -value only to 
refer to Incremental quantities and never to sulDdivide 
aggregate surplus -value . "Absolute sur pi lis -value" is 
to be defined as that change in surplus -value caused by 
a change in the duration of the working -period , and 
"relative surplus -value" is to be defined as that change 
in surplus -value caused by a change in the duration of 
the necessary labor-time (i.e,. of the "paid" portion of 
the working period .) In all subsequent use of the terms 
"absolute" and "relative" surplus -value these definitions 

are ^^hat is meant. 

The relation between absolute and relative surpl\js 

value may be illustrated simply as follows: 

An average laborer vorking a 40 hour veek at a 
rate of surplus -value of 100^ will produce surplus -value 
to the amount of 20 labor -units . If his hours of work 
per -week are Increased to 48 "while the labor-content of 
his vage drops to 16 units due to an increase in pro- 
ductivity he will then produce 32 units of surplus -value 
per week. The increase of 12 units is composed of 8 
units of absolute surplus -value and 4 units of relative 
surplus -value . The rate of surplus -value will of course 
have been doubled . 

Put algebraically, this relationship can be 



41 



analyzed in this vay: 

If the vorking-day changes from Y hours to X hours j the 
productivity of labor per-hoiir increases by a^, the real 
wage per -hour increases by b^, and the original rate of 
exploitation is ^ ', 

Absolute SurplxiS -Value is equal to X - Y 

Y ( a-b ) 
Relative Surplus -Value is equal to i^^j- {\^q) 

The New Rate of Surplus -Value is — Y (itbj ~ "'" 
These categories are important for the analysis 
of variations in real wages and in the length and inten- 
sity of the working day, variations which have a radically 
different significance according to whether they are simul- 
taneous in a given society or represent the result of 

changes over time . 

In the production of absolute surplus -value Marx 
regards a simultaneous difference in the Intensity of 
work as equivalent to a difference in the duration of 
work. "The value created varies with the extent to which 
the intensity of labor deviates from its normal inten- 
sity in the society. A given working-day, therefore, 
creates no longer a cons tant but a variable value ." 

But just as we saw to be the case with "skilled 
labor," this equivalence does not apply to changes over 



1. Capital , I, 57f 



42 



time in the average intensity of labor itself. "If the 
Intensity of lahor were to increase simultaneously and 
equally in every branch of industry, then the new and 
higher degree of intensity vould become the usual and 
normal degree for the society, and would cease to be 
taken into account as an extensive magnitude." 

If the duration of the working-day is unchanged , 
absolute surplus -value, an "extensive magnitude," cannot 
arise. The opposite is the case with relative surplus- 
value, which arises from an "intensive magnitude.," the 
productivity of labor . Every change in this productivity 
must ultimately affect the relative share of the working- 
day devoted, at a given real wage, to "'necessary labor." 

Absolute surplus -value thus cannot result from 
historic changes in the average degree of Intensity or 
skill. The converse of this is that relative surplus - 
value cannot result from simultaneous differences in the 
value of labor -power: in other terms, assuming that all 
workers receive a wage proportional to the value of their 
labor-power (defined by Marx as "the value of the neces- 



1. Capital , I, 575* 

2 on the distinction between "extensive" and "intensive" 
magnitudes, derived by Marx from Hegel's, Logic, see 
Naville, op. clt ., pp. 377-378. 



45 



sarles of life habitually required" plus "the expenses 
of developing that labor -poweil') , it T^ould follow that 
all produce surplus -value at the sam e rate of exploita- 
tion . Or, to put the same idea in rigidly "orthodox" 
terms: in equilibrium the ratio between the wages of 
any two workers is equal to the ratio between their 
marginal products . 

No less a Marxist than Hilferding, however, has 

disputed the above proposition: 

To deduce the value of the product of 
labor from the wage of labor conflicts grossly 
with the Marxist theory. . . . Even if the 
rate of exploitation of unskilled labor were 
known to me, I should have no right to assume 
that the identical rate of exploitation pre- 
vailed for skilled labor. For the latter the 
rate of er.ploitation might be much lower. 

If this be true, then the amount of surplus -value depends, 
not on the quantity of concrete labor performed at a 
given rate of exploitation, but on the shapes of the dis- 
persion of skills and of rates of exploitation, a con- 
cept impossible to work with empirically. 

Fortunately Hilfer ding's argument can be shown 
to be based on a misinterpretation of a single sentence 
from Marx: "1st der Wert dieser Kraft hoher, so aussert 
sie sich daher auch in hoherer Arbeit und vergegenstand- 
licht sich daher, in denselben Zeitraum.en, in verhalt- 



1. Hilferding, op. cit ., p. l42. 



,N 44 



nissmassig hoheren Werten."^ Hilferdlng argued that, 
because in the second German edition of Das Kapital 
the word "aber" (however) stood in place of the first 
"daher" (consequently), the sense of the passage "is 
somewhat as follows: 'Even though the value of this 
power be higher, it can none the less produce more sur- 
plus =value, because it manifests itself in higher work' 

- and so on."^ 

With his confusion between the "aber" of the 
second edition and the "daher" of the third, and his 
little phrase "and so on," Hilferding has quite simply 
blotted out the key concept of this passage: that labor- 
powers of higher value "objectify themselves ... in a 
proportionately ( verbal tnissmassig ) higher mass of value." 
Marx thus is saying quite bluntly that the value created 
is proportional to the value of the labor power, that the 
rates of exploitation are equal . 

In a later part of Volume I Marx is, if possible, 
even more explicit. This is the discussion of piece 
wages , which Marx considers " the form of wages most in 
harmony with the capitalist mod e of production." and 



1. Das Kapital , I, 206, in translation, "This power being 
of higher value, it consequently also manifests itself xn 
superior labor and therefore is objectified, in equal spaces 
of time, in a proportionately higher mass of value. 

2. Hilferding, op. cit ., p. 142. 

3. Capital , I, 608. 



45 



■which of course consist of paying a relative wage cor- 
responding directly to relative productivity, and thus 
directly carrying out the process of expressing qualita- 
tively different concrete labor-powers as expressions of 
homogeneous, abstract, social labor, differing only 

quantitatively: 

With regard to actual receipts there is, there- 
fore, great variety according to the different 
skill, strength, energy, staying -power, etc., of 
the individual laborers. Of course this does 
not alter the general relations between capital 
and wage -labor. First, the individ ual differ- 
ences balance one another in the workshop as a 
whole, which thus supplies in a given working - 
time the average product, and the total wages 
paid will be the average wages of that particu- 
lar branch of industry. Second, the proportion 
between wa^es and surplus -value remai ns unaltered, 
since the mass of surplus -lab or supplied py each 
particular laborer corresponds with th e wage re- 
ceived by him .-'^ 

Piece-wages are the form of wages "most in harmony 
with the capitalist mode of production" because, despite 
transitory divergences between the relative value and rela- 
tive price of specific labor-powers, in the long run 
labor-power, unlike other commodities, tends to sell at 
its value and, in a competitive factor -market, tends to 
be allocated in such a way that the product, and hence 
the surplus product, of each laborer "corresponds with 
the wage received by him." 



1. Capital , I, 607 (italics mine). 



46 



Consequently, relative surplus -value can only 
result from changes in the value of labor- power over time, 
and absolute surplus -value , over time, only from changes. 
in the duration of the vorking-day . The factors deter- 
mining these magnitudes and their changes are identically 
those determining the rate of exploitation. 

The rate of exploitation is the immediate repre- 
sentation of the prevailing social relationship betveen 
the two fundamental classes, and as such its quantitative 
determination cannot be the result of "pu.re" economic 
causes. This is most immediately apparent in the length 
of the working-day, whose basic duration is presently 
fixed by legislation, itself the outcome of long political 
and social struggles. Accordingly Marx declares: 

We see then that, apart from extremely elastic 
bounds, the nature of the exchange of commodi- 
ties itself imposes no limit to the working- 
day, no limit to surplus -labor . . . . There is 
here, therefore, an antinomy, right against 
right, both equally bearing the seal of the 
law of exchanges . Between equal right s force 
decides . Hence is it that in the history of 
capitalist production, the determination of 
what is a working-day presents itself as the 
result of a struggle, a struggle between col- 
lective capital, i.e., the class of capitalists, 
and collective labor, i.e., the working class .J- 

Thus absolute surplus -value is determined by 

"force," and we know that the past four generations have 



1. Capital , I, 259 f italics mine. 



47 



seen a prevailing tendency towaru reciuction of the working- 
day. With relative surplus -value, on the other hand, -we 
seem at first glance to be dealing -with an economically 
determined cause, the value of lahor-power, vhich, Marx 
states, "is determined by the value of the necessaries 
of life habitually required by the average laborer," 
that is, the value of the "real_wage_." 

li/hat hovever, determines the quantity of "neces- 
saries of life" whose value determines that of labor - 
power? It is certainly not a physiological minimum deter- 
mined with the force of an "iron law"; on the contrary it 
is a socially and historically determined magnitude sub- 
ject to evolution: 

The number and extent of so-called necessary 
wants, as also the modes of satisfying them, 
are themselves the product of historical 
development, and depend therefore to a great 
extent on the degree of civilization of a 
country, 2 and in particular on the conditions 
under which, and consequently on the habits 
and degree of comfort in which, the class of 
free laborers has been formed. In contradis- 
tinction therefore to the case of other com- 



1. Capital , I, 568. 

2. Compare Ricardo: "It is not to be understood that 
the nat\n'al price of labor, estimated even in food and 
necessaries, is absolutely fixed and constant. It 
varies at different times in the same country and very 
materially differs in different countries. It essen- 
tially depends on the habits and customs of the people.'' 
David Ricardo^ Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo , 
Volume I, Principles of Political Economy (Cambridge, 
1951), P- 9^"^ 



48 



modities, there enters into the determina- 
tion of the value of la^or -power a historical 
and moral element .•'• 

For particular short-run partial analyses the 
real vage can be held constant, since "in a given country 
at a given period the average quantity of the means of 
subslstance necessary for the laborer is practically 
known." 2 Nevertheless in the long run the real wage is 
most definitely a variable quantity. The question is 
how far, and in what direction, can it be expected to 

vary? 

Perhaps the most widespread single misconception 

about Marx's view of capitalism, a misconception shared 
by anti -Marxists like John Strachey^ with the High 
Priests of Stalinist "Marxism" (of whom the foremost 
surviving specimen is Maurice Thorez), is the belief that 
Marx enunciated a "Law" of "Increasing Misery" or "Abso- 
lute Immlseratlon" or " Pauperization »" According to this 
"Law," the net effect of capitalist development would be 

to drive real wages, despite temporary fluctuations, 

Ij. 
down toward the absolute physiological minimum. 



1. Capital , I, 190. 

2. Ibid. 

S The failure of capitalism to comply with this alleged 
"Law" is the main thesis of his Contemporary Capitali sm 
(New York, 1956) . 

li A very valuable discussion of this matter is to be found 
in the article by T . Sowell, "Marx's 'Increasing Misery' 
Doctrine," ft pi^-rlcan Bc nnomic Review. L, No. 1 (March, 1950 j, 
111 ff. 



49 



Two citations are usually presented as evidence 
for this view. In the ''Communist Manifesto" of 1847 
Marx and Engels vrote: 

The modern laborer, on the contrary, instead of 
rising with the progress of industry, sinks 
deeper and deeper "oelow the conditions of exist- 
ence of his own class. He becomes a pauper, and 
pauperism develops more rapidly than population 
and wealth. And here it becomes evident that 
the bourgeoisie is unfit any longer to be the 
ruling class in society . . . because it is in- 
competent to assure an existence to its slave 
within his slavery, because it cannot help let- 
ting him sink into such a state that it has to 
feed him, instead of being fed by him.-"- 

Twenty years later, in Volume I of Capital, Marx stated: 

The greater the social wealth, the functioning 
capital, the extent and energy of its growth, 
and, therefore, also the absolute mass of the 
proletariat and the productiveness of its labor, 
the greater is the industrial reserve -army. 
The same causes which develop the expansive 
power of capital, develop also the labor -army 
at its disposal. The relative mass of the in- 
dustrial reserve -army increases therefore ex- 
ponentially "with wealth. But the greater this 
reserve -army in proportion to the active labor- 
array, the greater is the mass of a consolidated 
surplus -population, whose misery is in inverse 
ratio to its torment of labor. The more exten- 
sive, finally, the lazarus -layers of the working- 
class and the industrial reserve -army, the 
greater is official pauperism. This is t he abso- 
lute general law of capitalist accumulation . Like 
all other laws it is modified in its working by 
many circumstances, the analysis of which does 
not concern us here .^ 



1. "Communist Manifesto," in Karl Marx and Friedrich 
Engels, Capital and Other Writings (New York, 1932;, p. 333. 

2. Capital , I, 707- 



50 



The first of these passages, -which speaks of 
"the modern la"borer," can legitimately, though not con- 
clusively, iDe interpreted as a prediction of the im- 
poverishment of the working class. The second, however, 
which states Marx's thought in a much more developed 
way, gives no support for the "Immiseration" doctrine. 
What Marx is here concerned with is that portion of the 
labor-force more-or-less permanently unemployed as a 
result of capital-intensive technological progress. 
These are workers who have sunk " below the conditions 
of existence " of their class; who produce no more surplus- 
value, but must be fed at the expense of the ruling 
class. This is a stratum, Marx declares with mathemati- 
cal precision, "whose misery is in inverse ratio to its 
torment of labor (deren Elend im umgekehrten Verhaltnis 
zu ihrer Arbeitsqual steht) ."•'• In sura, Marx is talking 
about the West Virginia ex -coal -miner, not (or not yet) 
the Akron rubber -worker. 

"What then is Marx's actual analysis of the his- 
torical tendency of the real wage? As in the determina- 
tion of the working day, so in that of the real wage Marx 
places primary emphasis on bargaining power: 

The fixation of /the rate of surplus -value 's_7 
actual degree is only settled by the continuous 



1. Das Kapital , I, 679. 



51 



struggle tet^een capital and labor, the 
capitalist constantly tending to reduce 
wages to their physical minimum, and to 
extend the working day to its physical 
maximum, while the working man constantly 
presses in the opposite direction. 

The matter resolves itself into a 
question of the relative powers of the 
combatants . 

This bargaining process, however, always takes 

place in a context set by general economic conditions: 

a struggle for a rise of wages follows only 
in the track of previous changes, and is the 
necessary offspring of previous changes in 
the amount of production, the productive 
powers of labor, the value of labor, the value 
of money, the extent or the interiSity of labor 
extracted, the fluctuations of market prices, 
dependent upon the fluctuations of demand and 
supply, and consistent with the different 
phases of the industrial cycle ."^^ 

In this discussion of wages Marx maintains that 
"in its merely economical action capital is the stronger 
side," and thus that under capitalism "it is the nature 
of things" that "the general tendency of capitalist pro- 
duction is not to raise but to sink the average standard 
of wages, or to pash the value of labor more or less to 
its minimum limit ." 

All of this, however, still does not add up to a 
discussion of real wages; Marx is referring to the "value 



1. Karl Karx, Vslus ^ Price, and Profit (London, 1899), p. 88. 

2. Ibid., p. 84. 

3. Ibid., p. 92. 



52 



of labor" and considering struggles over wages as 
"efforts at maintaining the given value of labor." 

In fact Marx never declares explicitly that real 
wages must tend to rise in the course of capitalist 
development. This position, however, has a very strong 
implicit basis in Marx's general approach to the question. 

The theory that the level of real wages must 
tend to increase can be derived from several points in 
Marx's discussion of wages: 

(a) As we have seen, the "necessary wants" are 
dependent on the "degree of civilization." As capitalism 
develops, therefore, these "necessary wants" increase, 
so that the socially determined minimum grows relatively 
to a physiologically-determined subsistence level. A 
possible mechanism to bring this about is that increases 
in Y;orking-class living standards, when they partially 
correspond to the already-realized progress of other 
classes, would be regarded by the workers as permanent 
and psychologically incorporated into the "necessary 
wage • " 



1. Ibid ., p. 92. 

2. This point is made quite strongly in the essay by 
Sowell previously cited* 



53 



(b) Marx regards the expenses of education 
and training as factors determining the value of labor - 
pover, and states that these expenses "vary with the 
mode of production."^ To the extent that increasing 
productivity requires increased specialization, training, 
and literacy on the part of the average xJorker the neces- 
sary minimum real "wage is thereby increased. 

(c) Marx regarded the increasing intensity of 
work as a central aspect of economic development under 
capitalism. This increased intensity of labor, if not 
compensated by at least a proportional increase in real 
wages, would be physically ruinous to the worker. "By 
increasing the intensity of labor, a man may be made to 
expend as much vital force in one hour as he formerly 
did in two. In checking this tendency of capital, by 
struggling for a rise of wages corresponding to the ris- 
ing intensity of labor, the working man only resists the 
depreciation of his labor and the deterioration of his 
race."^ Thus increased real wages are necessary to the 
very self-preservation of the worker. 

(d) Finally, the growth of productivity allows 
for increases in real wages without any decrease in the 



1. C apital , I, 569. 

2. value. Price, and Profit , p. 82. 



54 



amount of surplus -value produced and even with an in- 
crease in surplus -value . When the value of consumption 
goods is falling, "it is possible with an increasing 
productiveness of labor for the price of labor-power 
to keep on falling and yet this fall to he accompanied 
by a constant growth in the mass of the laborer's means 
of subsistence .' 

This third means of raising the necessary real 
wage is available only to the extent that workers are 
organized and can compel capital to share with them the 
gains from increasing productivity. It " depends on 
the relative weight which the pressure of capital, on 
the one side, and the resistance of the laborer, on the 
other, throws into the scale . "^ And of course, in the 
most celebrated passage of Capital Marx speaks of the 
increasing "revolt of the working-class , a class always 
increasing in numbers, and disciplined, united, organized 
by the very mechanism of the process of capitalist pro- 
duction itself."^ 

The conclusion must be that if there is a "law" 
of real wages in the Marxian system it should be entitled, 
not the "Law of Increasing Misery" but the "Law of 



1. Capital , I, 573' 

2. Ibid . 

3. Ibid ., p. 783. 



55 



increasing Reaulreroentg ." And this indeed is hov Lenin, 

in 1593, put the matter: 

We must not lose sight of the indubit- 
able fact that the development of capitalism 
inevitably entails a rising level of require - 
nic»n-Hs ^'^■^ ^-^e entire population^ incluaing 
the industrial proletariat. This rise is 
. . . brought about by the crowding together, 
the concentration of the industrial proletariat 
vhich enhances their class consciousness and 
sense of human dignity and enables them to 
vage a successful struggle against the preda- 
tory tendencies of the capitalist system. ^ 
This lav of increasing requirements has maia- 
f as ted itself ^^th full force in the history 
of Europe - compare, for example, the French 
proletariat of the end of the eighteenth and 
of the end of the nineteenth centuries, or , 
the British worker of the 1840's and of today. 

What Marx clearly does expect is a decline, not 
of the real wage, but of the value of the real wage. He 
maintains that the continual increase in the potential 
labor-force due to the proletarianization of former 
peasants, artisans, and shopkeepers, in addition to the 
natural growth of population, will tend to exceed the in- 
crease in employment due to capital accumulation, particu- 
larly since he expects technological progress to be 
highly capital-intensive. 

If we assume, with Marx, that the structure of 
the labor market is or can be made essentially monopo- 



1. V. I. Lenin, "On the So-called Market Question," 
CollectedWoiM (Moscow, i960), I, 106. 



56 



lis tic ;, the existence of a growing "industrial reserve 
army" is perfectly consistent vith a rising real -wage 
level. But since this "monopoly power" of unions is 
at "best far from complete, and is confronted with at 
least as well organized a "monopsony power/' there are 
substantial economic forces working against a more than 
gradual tendency toward increasing real wages. Th\iS 
despite the increase in the real wage, "the abyss be- 
tween the laborer's position and that of the capitalist 
would keep widening"-^ if the working -day remains 

constant. 

IVhat then can be predicted on the basis of the 
Marxian system as to the long-run tendency of the rate 
of surplus -value? As we have seen, this change is made 
up of both absolute and relative surplus -value, but 
absolute surplus -value tends to be a negative , and rela- 
tive surplus -value a positive , magnitude. In other words, 
both the total working day and the duration of its "paid" 
portion tend to decrease in the long-run. There can 
therefore be no general economic law governing the move- 
ment of the rate of exploitation: it appears almost en- 
tirely as a function of the balance of social forces. 
Accordingly, despite violent short-term fluctuations, 
any long-run increase or decrease in the rate of exploita- 



1. Capital , I, 573. 



57 



tion would "be expected by Marx to show Itself only as 
an exceedingly slow and gradual trend. Marx himself 
expected the rate of surplus -value to increa-se in the 
long-run. Nevertheless, in terms of the Marxian sys- 
tem, the actual prevailing historical tendency of this 
rate cannot be predicted on theoretical grounds - it 
must be determined empirically. 

In analyzing the rate of surplus -value it re- 
mains to ascertain the concrete manifestations of the 
categories v and s_ in the capitalist economic system. 

v cannot be identified with the total wage -bill 

of the enterprise or of society. Marx defines it as 

representing exclusively the outlay on labor-power to be 

consumed as productive labor j the sole source of surplus - 

value : 

Capitalist production is not merely the pro- 
duction of Gom.modities, it is essentially 
the production of surplus -value .... That 
laborer alone is productive who produces 
surplus -value for the capitalist, and thus 
works for the self -expansion of capital . 
If we may take an example from outside the 
sphere of production of material objects , a 
schoolmaster is a productive laborer when, in 
addition to belaboring the heads of his 
scholars, he works like a horse to enrich the 
school proprietor. That the latter has laid 
out his capital in a teaching factory, instead 
of i-i a sausage factory, does not alter the 
relation . Hence the notion of a productive 
laborer implies not merely a relation between 
work and useful effect, between laborer and 
product of labor, but also a specific, social, 
relation of production, a relation that has 



\\ 



58 



sprung up historically and stamps the 
laborer as the direct means of creating 
surplus -value . 

Marx thus states two necessary conditions for 
labor to be productive: 

(a) The productive laborer must "vork for the 
self -expansion of capital" - his labor-power must ex- 
change with capital and not with revenue, he must work 
for a capitalist, not for the direct consider of his 
product. "A singer who sells her song on her own is an 
unproductive worker. But the same singer commissioned 
by an entrepreneur to sing in order to make money for 
him is a productive worker. For she produces capital." 

(b) The productive laborer must produce com - 
modities since surplus -value , like value in general, can 
only come into existence if it is embodied in a com- 
modity. However the commodity is not, as Adam Smith 
thought, defined as necessarily a durable material sub- 
stance. Marx makes it unequivocally clear that the ser- 
vices performed by schoolmaster and singer are commodities 
defined as such by their abstract characteristics as 
product of social labor and obiect of alienation. 

What, then, is unproductive labor? It is not 



1. Capital , I, 558 (italics mine). 

2. Theories of Surplus -Value , p. 186. 



59 



useless, aimless activity (vhich would be a type of 
leisure , not labor) . Unproductive labor is defined 
by Marx in its contrast to productive labor: it is 
that portion of the total social labor vhich produces 
no surplus -value because it is not engaged in commodity 
production or because it is not employed by a capitalist. 
There are thus vast domains of social activity^ notably 
the spheres of circulation and of government , in which 
the -wage -laborers are unproductive despite the formal 
Identity of their social position to that of wage- 
laborers in the productive spheres . 

Nevertheless, since it ranks ss social labor ^ 
unproductive labor must still be socially necessary . 
This follows from the fact that the work performed by 
these laborers is necessary to capital . "The capitalist 
mode of production begets . . . the creation of a vast 
number of employments, at present indispensable but in 
themselves superfluous.""^ Certainly a genuinely 
socialist comm^mity would require a vastly altered govern- 



1. Capital , I, 581 Cf. also J. Robinson, Essay , p. 20 n.: 
"The distinction /between productive and unproductive 
labor/ is clearly important. Industry and transport 
are necessary to society in a sense in which the activity 
of searching for buyers is not, and in the present age of 
advertising the distinction between production costs and 
selling costs is even more significant than it was in 
Marx's own day. 



60 



mental and aistributional system. But today the only 
relevant criterion is necessity for the functioning of 
capitalist society. 

Within the private capitalist sector, the Marxian 
division between productive and unproductive labor cor- 
responds quite closely to the \asual business bookkeeping 
and cost -accounting practice. The -wages of productive 
employees are costs , and go above the "gross -profit 
line" ; the payments to non-productive workers are ex- 
penses., and go below it. The Census of Manufactures 
classification of "Production and related -workers" like- 
wise corresponds to these categories: 

Workers (up through the working foreman 
level) engaged in fabricating, processing, 
assembling, inspection, receiving, storage, 
handling, packing, warehousing, shipping (but 
not delivering), maintenance, repair, jani- 
torial, watchman services, product develop- 
ment, auxiliary production for plant's own 
use (e.g. power plant), record keeping, and 
other services closely associated with these 
productive operations . 

Among non-" production -related workers" the 

Census definition includes: 

Factory supervision above the working fore- 
man level, sales, sales delivery, advertising, 
credit, collection, installation and servicing 
of own products, clerical and routine office 
functions, executive, purchasing, finance, 
legal, personnel, etc.^ 



1. U. S. Bureau of the Census, Census of Manufactures , 
195^ . (Washington, 1957), I, xvii. 



61 



With one minor exception (installation and 
servicing of own products) this enumeration quite con- 
forms to the Marxian definitions . 

For the same reason that v_ does not include the 
entire v?age bill, s_ does not stand for the total of 
"unpaid lahor" performed by tlie class of wage -workers . 
A great deal of social labor is "unproductive" ; never- 
theless the \inproductive laborer, exactly like the 
productive worker, sells his labor -power at a price ap- 
proximating its cost of production, and consequently 
also "performs partly unpaid labor ." 

Surplus -value thus is that portion of the social 
surplus -labor which assumes the form of value and in that 
form is appropriated by the property-owning classes . It 
is divided into three categories: "profit of enterprise," 
"interest," and "rent." 

It is here that profit is defined by Marx. Since 
commodities are sold at a price systematically diverging 
from their value, the surplus -value embodied in a com- 
modity alwa;^^ differs from the surplus -value realized 
by the capitalist producer. It is this latter quantity 
alone that constitutes profit from the viewpoint of the 
Individual capitalist. But on the scale of the whole 
society, if total interest and rent are added to the 



1. Capital , III, 354. 



62 



total profit, this aggregate must be equal to the aggre- 
gate surplus -value : 

In a capitalist society, this surplus -value 
... is divided among the capitalists as a 
dividend in proportion to the percentage of 
the total social capital held by each. In 
this shape the surplus -value appears as the 
average profit "wiiich, in its turn, is sepa- 
rated into profit of enterprise and interest, 
and \7hich in this way may fall into the hands 
of different kinds of capitalists . . . the 
landlord, in his turn, pumps a portion of this 
surplus -value, or surplus -product, out of the 
capitalist in the shape of rent. 

Hence, when spealcing of profit as that 
portion of surplus -value -which falls to the 
share of capital, we mean average profit 
(profit of enterprise plus interest) -which has 
already been limited by deducting the rent from 
the aggregate profits (identical in mass with 
the aggregate surplus -value .) Profits of 
capital (profit of enterprise plus interest) 
and ground-rent are merely particular con- 
stituents of surplus -value , categories by 
which surplus -value is distinguished according 
to whether it falls into the hands of capital 
or of private land. This classification does 
not alter its nature in any way. If added to- 
gether, these parts form the sum of the social 
surplus -value .-'■ 

If V, then, comprises only the wages of produc- 
tive laborers, and s is " identical in mas s" with the sum 
of prof it-of -enterprise, interest, and rent, how are the 
wages of unproductive labor to be treated? Although Marx, 
as we will see, provides in essence a clear explanation, 
he does not do so explicitly, and even seems to contradict 
himself in certain regards. This has led to gross misin- 



1. Capital , III, 955. 



63 



terpretationSj some commentators seeking to subsume 

these wages under "v,""'- others, 'with only slightly less 

violence to Marx's meaning, under "s.." 

Concretizing Sveezy's view, Gillman writes : 

In Marx's schema, 'profit' includes 
all income accruing to the capitalist 
above his prime and factory overhead costs, 
and is equivalent to the 'gross profit' in 
capitalist accounting practice. The whole 
congeries of administrative expense and 
selling costs, as well as rent, interest, 
eni business taxes, are all part of surplus - 
value . 3 

Having thus totally misconstrued the content 
which Marx ascribed to the category surplus -value , 
Gillman quite naturally got weird-looking results from 
his attempt at an empirical test of Marx's predictions 
concerning the rate of profit. In order to obtain a 
closer correspondence with the facts, he therefore in- 
serted into what he took to be the Marxian theory two 
new categories: "unproductive expenses" and "diminished 

s_" (net profit), the latter being equal to 3_-u. 

h. 
This is theoretically an indefensible procedure 



1. Cf. Robinson, Essay , p. 20, fn. 

2. Cf . Sweezy, The Theory of Capitalist Development , p. 279; 
"The employees in the commercial sphere are paid out of 
surplus -value ." 

3. Gillman, The Falling Rate of Profit , p. 17. 

4. In practice "s_-u" can be made equivalent to the 
Marxian s . 



64 



both "because it retains the erroneous definition of s_ 
and TDecai:^e in u and "diminished s_" it introduces 
categories which are not constituent parts of the value 
of the commodity and consequently cannot be integrated 
in the general Marxian model of capitalist production. 

A seeming justification for this approach, 
nevertheless, oan be found in a passage from volume II 
■which presents the expenses of circulation as "a deduc- 
tion from the surplus -value or surplus -product ." How- 
ever, in its proper context, even this passage points 
toward conclusions very different from those Gillman 
has drawn. In his original text Marx wrote: 

"Das allgemeine Geset;^ lat, das alle 
Zirkulationskosten, die nur aus der Form- 
verwandlung der Vfare entspringen, dieser 
letztren keinen Wert hinzusetzen. Es sind 
bloss Kosten zur Realisierung des Werts Oder 
zu seiner Uebersetzung aus einer Form in die 
andre. Das in diesen Kosten ausgelegte 
Kapital (eingeschossen die von ihm kommandierte 
Arbeit) gehort zu de n faux frais /uhproduktiven, 
aber notwendig Eos ten/ der kapitalistischen 
Produktion. Der Ersatz derselben muss aus dem 
Mehrprodukt geschehn, imd bildet, die ganze 
Kapitalistenklasse betrachtet, einen Abzug vom 
Mehrwert oder Mehrprodukt, ganz wie fur einen 
Arbeiter die Zeit, die er zum Einkauf seiner 
Lebensmittel braucht, verlorne Zeit ist."2 



lo Capital , II, 169. 

2. Das Kapital , II, 143, in translation, "The general law 
is, that all those expenses of circulation which only 
arise from changes of form of commodities, add no value 
to the latter. They are merely expenses required for 



65 



To understand this it is essential to realize 

that Marx refers to the expenses of circulation as "a 

deduction from the s\ir plus -value or surpliis -product" 

only "from the point of view of the entire capitalist 

class" and not from the standpoint of the process of 

capitalist production as a whole. For this process 

they are "necessary expenses" and no more a "deduction 

from surplus -value" than are the totality of hours of 

working time "lost time" to society, even though they 

appear as this to the working-class . In reality whs.t 

takes place in the unproductive spheres is simply the 

outlay of a determined and necessary co nstituent part 

of the total social capital : 

These costs form additional capital , but 
they produce no surplus -value . They must 
be made good out of the value of the com- 
modities . For a portion of the value of 
the commodities must once more be converted 
into these circulation costs; and no addi- 
tional surplus -value is created thereby. So 
far as this concerns the total capital of 
society it means that a portion of it must be 



the realization of value or for its conversion from one 
form into another. The capital laid out for these ex- 
penses (including the labor employed by it) belongs to 
the faux frais [unproductive but necessary expenses J of 
capitalist production. Its replenishment must be carried 
out from the surolus -product and forms, from the poinx 
of view of the entire capitalist class, a deduction from 
the surplus -value or surplus -product, just as, for a 
laborer', the time required for the purchase of his means 
of subsistence is lost time." 



66 



set aside for secondary operations which 
are no part of the process of creating 
value, and that this portion of the social 
capital must be continually reproduced for 
this purpose .1 

Since these commercial and political overhead 
expenses, though unproductive of ne'w value, signify the 
consumption of a portion of the social capital, the 
value consumed in this way, in order to assure its con- 
tinual reproduction, must enter into the total value 
of the mass of commodities produced. "The additional 
value, which the merchant adds to the commodities by 
his expenses, resolves itself into an addition of pre- 
viously existing values .'' 

As we saw earlier, the difference between vari- 
able and constant capital is founded on their differing 
modes of transferring value to the commodity-product; 
and in the case of constant capital this characteristic 
mode is precisely the addition of previously existing 
values . Consequently the appropriate treatment for the 
outlay on unproductive expenses in general, ' provided only 
that they are "socially necessary" under the existing 
form of social organization, is to regard them as part of 
the constant capital advanced and expended. 



1. Capital ^ III, 3^3, italics mine 

2, Ibid., p. 3^5. 



67 



Marx never explicitly defines the "unproductive 
but necessary expenses" of capitalist production as part 
of the constant capital, since in his reproduction 
schemata he abstracts entirely from the unproductive 
spheres (-which would complicate the analysis in several 
ways, including the seeming paradox that the fraction of 
the consumer-goods output consumed by unproductive 
laborers ^rjould have to be considered "capital goods" in 
a peculiar sense) and assumes, as in most places through- 
out Caciial, a society composed exclusively of capitalists 
and productive laborers . Nevertheless in the problem 
■with which the present study is concerned, that of the 
rate of profit, Marx is categorically clear that the 
necessary unproductive expenses are to be treated in 

that way: 

" Every expense of this kind . ♦ . reduces the 
rate of profit because the advanced capital Increases 
but not the surplus -value . If the surplus -value s. re- 
mains constant, while the advanced capital C Increases 

s 
to C :!- AC, then the place of the rate of profit - is 

taken by the smaller rate of profit q ^ ' ^q •" 

In practice unproductive expense and surplus - 
value can sometimes masquerade in each others form. 
Thus a large portion of top administrative salaries and 



1. Capital , III, 353, italics mine. 



68 



perquisites is merely a disguised form of profit while ^ 
in the opposite case, for "the actual retailers" a major 

part of their nominal profit is really only "^^ages for 

11 2 
labor - v?retched unproductive labor though it is . 

The Organic Composition of Capital 

The difference between constant and variable 
capital J as >7e have seen, reflects the fundamental dis- 
tinction between the "objective and subjective factors" 
of the labor process, between the means and conditions 
of production and living productive labor. The relation- 
ship between these two sides of the labor-process can 
be expressed quantitatively through a number of different 
ratios of which one, the "Organic Composition of 
Capital," is placed by Max in a pivotal position in his 
general theory. Marx defines this ratio in these 

terms : 

A definite number of laborers corresponds 
to a definite qusjitity of means and pro- 
duction, so that a definit e quantity of 
living labor corresponds to a definite 
Quantity of labor already objectified in 
means of production .-^ 



1. "On the basis of capitalist production a new swindle 
develops in stock enterprises with the wages of manage- 
ment. It consists of placing above the actual director 

a board of managers or directors, for whom superintendance 
and management serve in reality only as a pretext for 
plundering stockholders and amassing wealth. Capital, 
III, 458. 

2. Marx, Letter to Engels of April 30, 1868, in 
Correspondence , pp. 244=245. 

3. Capital , III, 171, Italics mine. 



69 



As Joan Robinson puts it, what Marx means by 
"organic composition" is simply " capital per man em - 
ployed" •*• (assuming a ^-/orking day of given length). It is 
t© he expressed quantitatively as the ratio bet^veen tvo 
quantities of labor -time: the value invested in means 
of production and the value nevly created during the 
production period . 

In algebraic form;, therefore, the organic com- 
position of capital is defined by the formula Q = ^^^g, j 

C 2 
or, equivalently, Q = -^=^— 

V • S 

Marx, however, is far from always expressing 

himself this clearly on the precise definition of what 

he means by "Organic Composition," and this has misled 

many commentators c Thu^ Gillman: 

Prom the formula ci-vi-s = c' Marx derived 
three ratios which served him as foundation 
stones for his theory of capitalist develop- 
ment. One of these is the ratio between c and 
V - between, constant capital consumed and 
variable capital consumed o This ratio, com- 
monly expressed as c/v, Marx called the orpianic 
composition of capital. He called it 'organic' 
becaiose it expresses the relations of the 
'dead' to the 'living' labor - of the constant 
to the creative qualities of the variable capi- 
tal .3 



1. Robinson, Essay , p. 8. 

2. Cf. Rolf Gusten, Die Langfristige Tendenz der Profitrate 
(Munich I960). 

3. Gillman, op. cit ., p. l6. 



70 



G-illman starts from the formula c-f-v+s = c»» 
But this is not the formula for capital , it is the formula 
for the commodity-produc t. The constant and variable 
capital consumed are not at all the necessary representation 
of the constant and variable capital involved in the pro- 
duction process. The former are flows , the latter stocks . 
Only if there exists no fixed capital, and if all portions 
of the circulating capital have equal periods of turnover, 
can these two ratios coincide e 

It is true that in many places Marx proceeds on 
just this assTomption, and thus generally operates with 
the - ratuo, assumed equivalent to the organic composition 

V 

as defined above. But for him it had exclusively the 
character of a drastic and unrealistic simplification, 
adopted solely for convenience in arithmetic illustrations. 
At all points Marx makes it very clear that, so far as 
constant capital is concerned, it is the invested capital 
("The mass of means of production employed") that is the 
basis for all ratios involving the composition of capital, 
and not the constant capital consumed in the total process of 
social production. By identifying the two, Gillman was led 
to a misleading and laborious computation of organic compo- 
sitions and rates of profit on a "flow basis," alongside his 
at least more relevant computations on a "stock basis." 



1. capital , I, 671, 



71 



However J recognizing that constant capital is 
to be computed exclusively on a "stock basis/' as the 
average Invested capital dioring a given period, clears 
up only the least of the difficulties. In the ratio 
C/v the symbols do not stand for the means of production 
and living labor employed, but for the values Invested 
in given quantities of labor-pover and means of produc- 
tion, vhich is not at all the same thing: 

The composition of capital is to be under- 
stood in a twofold sense. On the side of 
value J it is determined by the proportion in 
which it is divided into constant capital or 
value of the means of production, and variable 
capital or value of labor-power, the sum total 
of wages. On the side of material, as it func- 
tions in the process of production, all capital 
is divided into means of production and living 
labor-power. This latter composition is deter- 
mined by the relation between the mass of the 
means of production employed, on the one hand , 
and the mass of labor necessary for their em - 
ployment, on the other . I call the former the 
value -composition , the latter the technical 
composition of capital. Between the two there 
is a strict correlation. To express this, I 
call the value -composition, in so far as it is 
determined by its technical composition and 
mirrors the changes of the latter, the organic 
composition of capital. Wherever I refer to the 
composition of capital, without further quali- 
fication, its organic composition is always 
understood. 1 

From this passage Gillman comes to the conclusion that: 

Marx was very clear on the point that, whenever 
he dealt with the relation between the organic 
composition of capital and the rate of profit. 



1. Ibid., I, 671* Italics mine. 



72 



it was to 'value -composition' and not 'tech- 
nical composition' that he referred. It is 
in the value relations hetveen the constant 
and the variable capitals that Marx located 
this aspect of his theory of economic develop- 
ment .^ 

But if there is one thing clear here it is that 
Marx is saying notliing of the sortc The value -composi- 
tion can he assimilated to the organic composition only 
''in so far as it is determined hy its technical com- 
position and mirrors the changes of the latter" due to the 
existence of "a strict correlation" between the tv?o. 
This is by no means always the case: "Capitals of the 

same organic com.position may have a different value- 

2 
composition." 

By "technical composition" Marx essentially sig- 
nifies what modern economists call '" capital intensity/' 
the quantity of capital goods in "real" terms cooperating 
with each worker at some "normal" level of full employ- 

^ ^- 4-u^ -.oo-f-sr. Means of Production 
ment, the ratio ^^^er of worke Ti^ 

In what sense, then, can it be said that changes 
in this ratio have a "strict correlation" with changes in 
the value -composition? 

Value -composition (to which we arbitrarily attach 
the symbol R) Is given by the formula R = c/v. Technical 



1 . Gillman, p. 30* 

2. Capital , III, 890. 



73 



C • Iv 
composition (symlDol T) is then given by T = ^ * j^ (xv 

and Ic being the values of the price indexes for labor- 
power ana means of production, respectively.) 

A strict correlation will exist only if every 
relative change in gr will produce an identical relative 

change in R - i.e., if the elasticity of R with respect 

dR T ~ T 
to T is unitary. Unitary elasticity means that ^ * r " 

Since R = T If , f = § ana I r If , tto (|f)' -" L 

and Ic : Iv. 

This "strict correlation," therefore, can exist 
only if the price indexes themselves are always equal, a 
virtual impossibility. There is, moreover, an additional 
difficulty. Variable capital is "the index of ... a 
definite quantity of living labor set in motion" if and 
only if "the rate of surplus -value and the working day 
have been assumed to be constant and the wages for a 
definite working day are given." Marx throughout makes 
this assumption, but he makes it purely in order to sim- 
plify his exposition. In any attempt at analysis it must 
at a certain point be dropped, and Marx's failure to do 
so explicitly has resulted, not in simplification, but in 

enormoios confusion. 

The relationship between R and £. depends entirely 
on s_', the rate of surplus -value, since ^ ~ ^ i- s ' . Thus 



1. Ibid., pp. 172-173. 



74 



'Where s ' is constant by definitionsas we have seen to be 
the case in cross -section equilibrium, R and ^ are really 
equivalent to each other, and it is in this sense that 
Marx sometimes treats them as identical. If over time sj_ 
is considered variable, chaiiges in R will overstate or 
understate changes in g_ according to whether s± increases 
or decreases . 

On the long run tendency of the "Organic Composi- 
tion of Capital" Marx is categorical: Human progress, 
identical to the development of the productive forces, 
necessarily involves a steady increase in the technical 
composition of capital, and this must be reflected in an 
increasing organic composition: 

The progressively higher organic composition 
of the social capital is, in another way, but 
an expression of the progressive development 
of the social productive power of labor .1 

The Rate of Profit 

In the actual workings of a capitalist economy 
surplus -value, as such, is never directly perceptible. 
It attains reality only in its derivative form of profit 
(including, for purposes of this analysis, rent and in- 
terest..) Accordingly, it is only in this form that surplus' 
value can play its role as the goal and regulator of 



1. Lbid . , p. 248. 



75 



capitalist production. It operates directly as a con- 
stituent of the price of commodities > and only ultimately 
as a constituent of their value . 

As we saw at the outset, Marx insists upon the 
necessary divergence between the "value" of a commodity 
and its "exchange value" or "natural price." This diver- 
gence is a reflection of the fact that it is profit and 
not surplus -value that enters into price; and whereas 
surplus -value is entirely a function (given the rate of 
exploitation) of the variable capital consumed, profit 
is always calculated on the total capital advanced. 

Since the organic composition of capital (which 
in cross -section equilihriiim analysis is also equivalent 
both to capital -intensity and to " value -composition" ) 
differs from industry to industry (each having its own 
unique technology as well as specific material circum- 
stances) the quantitative equivalence of profit to sur- 
plus-value would impose a different rate of profit in 
every particular industry. But just as it is a formal 
condition of equilibrium for the marginal return to a 
"factor" to be the same in all its alternative uses, so 
is it a real tendency of a capitalist economy for capital 
to "flow" to areas where the highest profits are expected 
and out of the least profitable fields of investment, 
thus modifying existing supply-demand relationships in 
such a way as to reduce the previous profitability- 



76 



differential. Worked out to its end, this tendency 
would result in the formation of a single rate of 
profit prevailing throughout the economy. 

Accordingly^ the tendency tovard uniform profit- 
ability must result in relative commodity prices dif- 
ferent from relative values. Marx calls these equilib- 
rium prices the prices of production : "The price of 
production of a commodity is equal to its cost-price 
/I.e., ct-v7 plus a percentage of profit apportioned 
according to the average rate of profit, or, in other 
words, equal to its cost-price plus the average profit." 

This price of production is, of course, "the 
same thing as what Adam Smith calls natural price, 
Ricardo price of production or cost of production , and 
the physiocrats prix ne cess aire" . . . and the same as 
Marshallian "long run average cost." It acquires its 
specifically Marxian form on only one "basis? that of 
the determination of the average rate of profit itself. 
This rate of profit is essentially the ratio -|- ^ov the 
total economy, the ratio of aggregate surplus -value to 
aggegate capital. "The general rate of profit arises 
through the total surplus -value produced being calculated 



1. Capital , III, 186. 

2. Ibid., p. 233. 



77 



on the total capital of the community (the class of 

X ..1 
capit-allsts) . 

The aggregate surplus -value , then, enters into 
the product of every capitalist in proportion to his 

invested capital: 

The various capitalists, so far as 
profits ere concerned, are just so many 
stockholders in a stock company in which 
the shares of profit are irnif ormly divided 
per 100, so that profits differ in the case 
of the individual capitalists only in ac- 
cordance vith the amount of capital invested 
hy each in the aggregate enterprise, i.e., 
according to his investment in social pro- 
duction as a -whole, according to the number 
of his shares .2 

The identity of aggregate surplus -value to ag- 
gregate profit is thus held by Marx to reconcile, on 
the level of the whole economic system, the micro - 
economic disparity bet-ween the value and the price of 
production of individual commodities : 

The sum of all the prices of production 
of all commodities in society, comprising 
the totality of all lines of production, iS 
equal to the sum of all their values. 3 

The relation between the value and the price of 

production of a given line of industry, as conceived by 

Marx, can be presented in a precise algebraic form. 



1. Theories of Surplus -Value , p. 337- 

2. Capital , III, 187- 

3. Ibid., p. 186. 



1, "1 



/^'■- 78 



though Marx himself failed to do soo 

As we have seerij the organic composition of a 
given capital or of the social capital as a whole is 

r* S ^'7 

given by Q = ^ ^ . i , the rate of profit "by ' — ^-^j 

and, by substitution, p' = s' ^ C, the stock of 

QU ^ s*) 

invested constant capital, is related to o, the con- 
stant capital consumed, by a rate of turnover t (here 
assumed to be given and uniform throughout the economy) 
so that c = Cto In addition we represent the ratio of Qi, 
the organic composition of capital in industry i,to the 
organic composition of the social capital by A ^^ = —o 

The value (^) of the product of industry 1, then, 
is equal to 

®i * "'^i * '^1'^' ~ ^"'^i ^^'^ ^*^ ^ '^ ^1 ^^ ^' ^^^ 
Zi = vi (1 •^ s*) (Qj^t •«' 1) 

Its price of production (Pi), correspondingly, 

Q* s* V4 
is given by c^ 4- Vj^ * p»C = Q^v^ (1 * s») t + v^^* -i — J: 

^i - ^i ^'h ^^ * ^^' * * ^^"^ ^* ^1^^ 

The "transformation coefficient" between price 

of production and value for industry i, ^^, is thus 

Pi viLOi (1 + s») t + (1 + s' Ai) 3 

determined by the ratio ■=- = — - — rr-r — r- — 77: — ^ ^ -. — 

Zj. V. (± + s«; (Qi t * 1) 

e^i = 1 * s' 

Oj^ t + 1 
while for the entire economy Z 0-1?. 



79 



For a further disciission of this quetstion, see 
Appendix A . 

Summary 

The net product during a given period has a 
value equal to the number of hours of productive labor 
expended by the members of society, productive labor 
being defined as the work done by laborers employed by 
capital and directly or indirectly necessary for the 
production of commodities . The gross product has a 
value identical to the sujn of the prices of the final 
products in the sj^stemo 

The difference in value bet-ween the gross and 
net products is defined as the constant capital consumed. 
The value of the net product consists of variable capital , 
the total wage received by the productive laborers, and 
stir plus -value , the total of property incomes in the fcrms 
of profit, interest and rent. The capital consumed in 
unproductive but necessary areas of the economy counts 
as pert of the constant capital, and enters into the 
value of the gross, but not the net, product. 

The value of the total invested capital can be 
regarded as representing entirely a stock of constant 
capital, and under tliis assumption the basic categories 
of the Marxian system are expressed by the four symbols 
C,c.,v, and s_ - representing respectively the average 



80 



A\ 



Stock of capital, the constant capital consumed, the 
variaMe capital consumed, and the surplus -value 
produced during the year. 

These economic aggregates are linked "by three 
fundamental quantitative relationships: the rate of 
surplus -value or rate of exploitation, s.' ; the organic 
composition of capital, 9,; and the rate of profit, £' . 
These ratios are determined hy: 

s' = s 

v 



Q = 



_ c 



v^s 



p. - s 



C 

The general inter -relationship of the system is 
expressed hy the equation: 

"ollTs^ 



p, - s' 



81 



CHAPTER III 



THE LAV/ OF THE PALLING TENDENCY OF THE RATE OF 
PROFIT AS PRESENTED BY MARX 



Marx's Formulation of the "Law" 

The idea that economic development is inescapably 
accompanied by a secular decline In the rate of profit was 
by no means original with MarXo On the contrary, when 
Marx wrote this proposition had been for nearly two cen- 
turies generally accepted as a social law as well as a fact 
of experience. Its status as a dogma is Indicated by the 
admission of Profo Shadwell, who in 1^77 denied the exis- 
tence of such a tendency, that "this theory, however, is 
in opposition to the unanimous opinion of all other Politi- 
cal Economists, who maintain that there is a constant fall 

2 
of profit as society advances, " 

As to the cause of this tendency, however, there 
was no such unanimltyo "The economists saw the problem, " 
wrote Marx, "and oudgeled their brains in tortuous attempts 
to inteirpret it. Since this law is of great importance 



1, Cfo G. U So Tucker, Progress and Profits in British 
Sconomio Thought, 1630-IS50 (Cambridge, 19faO)o 

2o "A System of Political Economy, " po 165, cited in 'Tucker, 
oPe cit» , p. 3» 



82 



for capitalist production, it may be said to be that 
mystery ^hose solution has been the goal of the entire 
political economy since Adam Smltho " 

Marx claimed that the "riddle" was solved through 
his analysis of capital into constant and variable com- 
ponents and the relationship between them expressed in the 
"organic composition of capltalo " 

The basis of Marx's thesis is the assertion of a 

secularly rising tendency of the organic composition of 

capital, reflected in a similar tendency of the "value 

composition"? 

We have seen that it is one of the laws of 
capitalist production that its development 
carries with it a relative decrease of 
■variable as compared with constant capital, 
and consequently as compared to the total 
capital which it sets in motion, 2 

If the rate of exploitation is assumed to remain 
constant or virtually so, the amount of profit is essen- 
tially proportional to the number of worfeers ©mployedo 
Since, however, the value invested as capital for each 
worlsjer is steadily increasing, the ratio of the mass of 
profit to the mass of capital must decline ; 

This progressive tendency of the average 
rate of profit to fall is, therefore, but 



io Capital , III, 25O0 
2. Ibid., p, 2^. 



83 



a peculiar expression of capitalist produc- 
tion for the fact that the social productivity 
of labor is progressively increasing. This is 
not saying that the rate of profit may not fall 
temporarily for other reasons. But it demon- 
strates at least that it is the nature of the 
capitalist mode of production, and a logical 
necessity of its development, to give expression 
to the average rate of surplus -value by a 
falling rate of average profit. Since the mass 
of the employed living labor is continually on 
the decline compared to the mass of objectified 
labor incorporated in productively consumed 
means of production, it follo-ws that that 
portion of living labor, which is unpaid and 
represents surplus -value, must also be continu- 
ally on the decrease compared to the volume 
and value of the invested total capital. 
Seeing that the proportion of the mass of 
surplus -value to the value of the invested 
total capital forms the rate of profit, 
this rate must fall continuouslyol 

Cf t 

Putting this in terms of the equation p« = .^^^^ . ^ 

it is clear that if s ' is constant the rate of profit is 
a decreasing function of Q, so that if Q increases over 
time p' must tend to decrease over time. 

The mechanism by -which the fall in the rate of 
profit is brought about, according to Marx, is the same 
as that by which the mass of profit is increased: the 
accumulation of capital . For this reason Marx calls it 
"the two-faced law," 

Every competitive entrepreneur, in order to maintain 



1. Ibid., p. 249. 



84 



his pr-oflts both in mass and rate, seeks simultaneously 
to increase the volume of his ps^oductlon and to lower its 
average cost. His gross Investment, expended on the most 
advanced (and hence, on Marx's assumption, the most capital- 
intensive) means of production, is simultaneously capital^ 
broadening as well as capital-deepening, since it will 
provide facilities for the employment of a larger quantity 
of labor-potfero In the short run the innovator, on the 
basis of his temporary "monopoly^ of the new technique, 
is able to sell his goods at close to their former price 
of production, thus attracting to himself a higher-than- 
proportional share of the total surplus- value and raising 
his own rate of profit above the social average * 

When the innovation is fully diffused, however, 
it no longer provides a higher rat© of profit since the 
"monopolistic" situation has dlsappearedo The new 
average rate of profit will be lower than previously be- 
cause of the general increase in the organic composition 
of the total capital even though, given a constant rate 
of exploitation, the total profit will have increased due 
to the employment of a greater number of workers. 

This, then, is the "Law of the Falling Tendency 
of the Bate of Profit" as Marx presents it in Chapter XIII 
of vol. Ill, "Sas Gesetz als solches. " It has exclu- 
sively the character of a long run tendency of capitalist 



85 



evolution; but one which is always in operation inasmuch 
as "The capitalist process of production is essentially 
at the same time a process of accumulation, " 

In this chapter, however, Marx remains on an ex- 
tremely high level of abstraction in which, in general, 

1) the rate of exploitation is assumed to be constant, 

2) the inoreae© in the organic composition of capital Is 
treated as a simple reflection of the increasing pro- 
ductivity of labor, and 3) thelon^-^ran rate of profit 
and the influences upon it are isolated from the fact org 
governing the short and intermediate range behavior of 
overall economic activityo The next two chapters, 
"Entgegenwirkende Ursachen" ("Counteracting Causes") and 
"Entfaltung der Innern Wldersprfiche des Gesetzes" ("Un- 
ravelling of the Internal Contradictions of the law"), 
make the analysis considerably more realistic and concrete, 

The Oountervailini? Factors 

In the Marxian formula p« « b« , 2I «i2.1 be 

Q(l48') 

increased either by an increase in 8j_ or a decrease in £. 
Thus forces offsetting a tendency of 2L *° f&ll must work 
either through Increasing the rate of exploitation or de- 
creasing the organic composition of oapitalo 



lo Ibid. , p. 255. 



86 



Such forces, furthermore, may have effects of two 
different sortss the first express long-term, fundamental 
Immanent tendencies of capitalist evolution which must be 
regarded as an integral part of Marx's theory of the 
falling tendency of the rate of profit itself; the others 
are of an exclusively short-run variety, events either of 
a unique or self-reversing nature. 

Only effects of the latter type can really be re- 
garded as produced by <* countera cting cause Se " Marx, 
however, though he is explicit that "the same causes 

which bring about a tendency of the rate of profit to 

1 

fall, also check the realization of this tendency, " 
treats causes of this sort together with those of a 
genuinely » counteracting" nature, without clearly dis- 
tinguishing between them. 

Marx enumerates five different main counteracting 
causes i "Raising the Intensity of Exploitation," "Cheapen- 
ing of the Elements of Constant Capital," "Depression of 
Wages below their Value, » "Relative Overpopulation, " and 
"Foreign Trade." Of these the first two have (in part 
only, as we will see) the nature of permanent and funda- 
mental tendencies; the others are short-term possibilities 
available to concrete capitalist economies. 



1. Ibid., p, 277. 



87 



The long-term tendency of the rate of eacploltation 
was discussed in Chapter lo At that time we saw that, 
secularly, absolute surplus-value is a negative, and rela- 
tive surplus-value a positive, magnitude. Accordingly 
their resultant is an expression of the balance of social 
forces, of the "class struggle," and Is not mechanically 
determined by economic or technological variables, A 
secular rise in the rate of exploitation cannot therefore 
be deduced from the Marxian system„ Marx himself seems 
to have expected such a rise to take place, and in the 
discussion on "counteracting causes" he operates under the 
specific assumption that this will be the cases "The 
falling tendency of the rate of profit la accompanied by 

a rising tendency of the rate of surplus- value , that is, 

1 
the rate of exploitation. •« 

The question whether this hypothetical "rising 
tendency of the rate of exploitation" can be so strong as 
to negate completely the effects of a rising organic com- 
position of capital will be examined later. In terms of 
"counteracting causes" we are here concerned with short- 
term effects. 

Marx presents three main ways in which the rate 
of exploitation may be raised in the short run; intensi- 



1. Ibid. , p, 221. 



88 



fioatlon of work, prolongation of the working day, and 
"the temporary but always recurring, elevations in surplus- 
value above the general level which keep occurring now in 
this and now in that line of production redounding to the 
benefit of those individual capitalists who make use of 
inventions etc, before these are introduced elsewhere, " 

The first two of these are at best temporary and 

2 
self -reversing. As was shown previously, more intense 

work represents a greater drain on the "vital forces" of 
the workers and therefore Increases the subsistenoe level 
of the real wage. Under Harz's assumption that labor 
power in the long run is sold at its value , this implies 
an ultimate increase in real wages "corresponding to the 
rising intensity of labor." Similarly, every extension 
of the working-day must be followed fairly soon by at 
least an equal contraction, in view of the empirical fact 
of a prevailing secular decline in hours worked per man 
per year. 

Finally, it is hard to see i4hj Marx included the 
effect of innovations for particular capitalists as a 
counteracting cause (he himself gives no explanation). 
It would seem that such innovations produce relative 



lo Ibid. , p. 22g. 

2. Of. supra , ch, II, p. 53. 



89 



surplus-value only as a function of their higher productivity, 
and hence their higher organic composition. And if the 
overall rate of surplus-value remains constant the excej)- 
tional profits of particular capitalists must he balanced 
by be loK^average profits for others. 

"Raising the Intensity of Exploitation, " according- 
ly, has two contrasting aspects: an assumed secular in- 
crease in the rate of exploitation as a consequence of the 
increasing productivity of labor; and a number of possible 
short-run methods of increasing relative or absolute sur- 
plus-value, gains which, however, must speedily prove 

ephemeral, 

"Cheapening of the Elements of Constant Capital, " 
likewise, ia primarily an immanent tendency of capitalist 
development, and Marx explicitly describes it as such: 

the same development, which increases the 
mass of the constant capital relatively 
over that of the variable, reduces the value 
of its elements as a result of the increasing 
productivity of labor. In this way the 
value of the constant capital, though 
steadily Increasing, is prevented from in- 
creasing at the same rate as its real volume, 
that is. the real volume of the means of 
production set in motion by the same amount 
of labor-power o^ 

But in what sense is this a "counteracting cause" 
to the increasing organic composition of capital? Rather 



1, Capital, III, 276. 



90 



Is it merely a statement that the organic composition 
itself must grow more slowly than the technical composl° 
tion of capital, maintaining in full force the "law" that 
the organic composition of capital must steadily increase 
(a proposition whose theoretical validity will be examined 
later ) „ 

Marx continues { 

In exceptional cases the mass of the ele- 
ments of constant capital may even increase, 
while its value remains the same or even 
faliSo"*- 

These "exceptional cases," then, provide the true 
short=run "conteracting eauseo" Mars is here referring 
particularly to increasing efficiency in the utilization 
of raw materials, reduction of waste, development of by- 
products, etCo A temporary spurt of strongly wcapital- 
saving" innovations of this sort could conceivably block 
the rise of the organic composition of capital or even 
cause it to fall, preventing the rate of profit from 
falling for this reason^ But given the existence of a 
rising secular tendency of the organic composition of capi- 
tal, such "exceptional eases" must be followed by a sharp 
though temporary rise in ^, as it returns to its trend 
value o 



1. Ibid. , po 277. 



91 



We C5an nm discuss the remaining "counteracting 
causes" which do not have this immanent aspeote 

On "depression of Vlagee "below their Value" Iferx 
merely states that this "has nothing to do with the general 
analysis of capital hut belongs in a presentation of com- 
petition, which is not given in this worko Hov;ever it is 
one of the most important causes checking the tendency of 
the rate of profit to fallo" 

"The Depression of Wages below their Value" clearly 
means the reduction of the real wage below the previous 
quantity of "necessaries of life habitually consumed by 
the average laborer o" Since, as we have seen, this quan- 
tity tends to rise with the development of capitalism, any 
fall in it can only be temporary, to be followed by a strong 
over-compensation. However, under the impact of the 
cyclic movement of the capitalist economic system, signifi- 
cant periodic decreases in the real wage may conceivably 
take place, and the , consequence of each could only be a 
marked, though transient, increase in the rate of profit. 

The fourth counteracting cause, "Relative Over- 
population," cannot act as such in a purely capitalist 
economy - its effects are based on the fact that "the im- 
perfect subordination of labor to capital continues in 



le Ibid., po 276. 



92 



Fiany lines of production, and continues longer than seems 

at first glance compatible with the general stage of de- 

1 
^elopmento"' But capitalistic techniques must ultimately 

invade these sectors as wells 

neif lines of production are opened up, 
especially for the production of luxuries, 
and these lines take for their basis this 
relative overpopulation set free in other 
lines of production by the increase of 
their constant capitalo These new lines 
start out with living labor as their pre- 
dominating element, and go by degrees through 
the same evolution as the other lines of 
production o'=i 

This possibility, however, is available to a 
eaptialist economy primarily in th© early stages of its 
growth, when non^capitalist sectors (artisans, individual 
peasant farmers), account for a sizable portion of national 
income — and even then only if these sectors sell their 
products to the capitalist sector at prices more or less 
corresponding to values (ioC,, only if they are not al- 
ready being exploited as internal colonies )» Thus its 
effect as a counterweight to a falling tendency of the 
rate of profit can at best be very slight, although ex- 
pansion into certain types of services remains a possi- 
bility throughouto 



lo Ibid. , V, 277. 

2. Ibid^, Italics mine. 



93 



A much more significant oounterr^lght is provided 
by the general category of "Foreign Trade." This effect, 
according to Marx, is brought about in two different wayso 
One is the expanaion of trade with other capitalist econo- 
mies s 

To the extent that foreign trade cheapens 
partly the elements of constant capital, 
partly the necessities of life for which 
the variable capital is exchanged, it tends 
to raise the rate of profit by raising the 
rate of surplus-value and lowering the 
value of the constant capital. It exerts 
itself generally in this direction by per- 
mitting an expansion of the scale of pro-» 
ductlono^ 

In this sense, as a means for realizing economies 
of scale, foreign trade is nothing more than the inter- 
national projection of th© Immanent tendencies of capi- 
talist evolution previously discussed under the headings 
"Raising the Intensity of Exploitation" and "Cheapening 
the Elements of Constant Capital^ — and analytically can 
in no way be separated from them. 

Matters are very different with respect to the 
other domain of foreign trade; trade with a country »0 
colonies. Here, Marx contends, is to be found a most 
substantial force supporting the rate of profit in the 
metropolis. In the first place, "In competition with 
commodities produced in other countries TJith lesser 



1, Ibid., III. 27s. 



94 



facilities of production „ „ o an advanced country is 

enabled to sell its goods above their value « » « labor 

of the advanced countries is here exploited as a labor of 

a higher specific weight, the rate of profit rises because 

labor which has not been paid as being of a higher quality 

1 
is sold as sucho" (In itself this "comparative advantage" 

argument implies no exploitation of one economy by another 
the capitalists of both are gainers by ito This, how- 
ever, is totally reversed when the advanced country holds 
both a monopolistic and monopsonistic position, enforced 
by direct or indirect political domination. Then the dis- 
persed native producers of primary products will have to 
sell to a single buyer able to impose a price below that 
which might be offered by other buyers, while metropolitan 
manufactured goods are sold at a level artificially main- 
tained through protective tariffs. Trade itself thus 
becomes a means of colonial sxploitatlon. This, of 
course, is the general rule — few colonial powers have 
ever practiced the ^open door policy" In their own pos- 
sessions, ) 

Of no less importance are the profits stemming from 

direct Investments 

Capitals Invested in colonies may yield a 
higher rate of profit for the simple reason 



1, Ibid., po 272, 



95 



that the rate of profit is higher there on 
account of the backward level of develop- 
ment, and for the added reason that slaves, 
coolies, etc., permit a better exploitation 
of labor 0^ 

Marx does not develop these points further, since 
this question "by its special nature is really beyond the 
scope of our analysiSo"^ Nevertheless they form the haalB 
on which the followers of Mam subsequently developed their 
theoretical analysis of imperiaxism,- 

Thls is, indeed, a point at which the Marxian 
economic analysis merges completely into politics. Since 
the general rate of profit includes profits extracted from 
the colonies, any tendency of this rate of profit to fall 
cannot be counteracted by mere maintenance of the existing 
level of colonial profits. What is required is the con- 
tinuous ejcpansion of the colonial sector relative to a 
metropolitan economy that is itself csqjanding. 

Once all available territories have been colonized, 
however, this expansion of the colonial sector can only 
come through conquest from another colonial power (i.e., 
world war) , or else through more intensive exploitation 
of existing colonies, a process which finds political 



le Ibid . , po 279. 

2o Ibid,, p. 278. 

3. Of. Vo lo Lenin, Imperialism, The Highest Stage of 
Capitalism (New York, 19^), pp. I38-140. ~ 



96 



limits in the form of revolutionary nationalist move- 
ments and economic limits in the generally backward and 
unbalanced structure of the colonial economyo (In his 
pamphlet on Imperialism , however, Lenin appears to Ignore 
these economic limits? "The export of capital greatly 

a-Pfects and accelerates the development of capitalism in 

1 
those countries to which it is exported,") In any case, 

as capitalism develops in the metropolis imperialism be- 
comes progressively less able to offset a falling tendency 
of the metropolitan rate of profit, even though colonial 
"super-profits" might well make the absolute level of that 
rate higher than it would other-«-lse be* 

Thus we see that, leaving aside for the present the 
immanent tendencies toward an increase in sj_ and a relative 
decrease in £ as compared to T, the "counteracting causes" 
enumerated by Marx can have at most a temporary effect in 
supporting the rate of profit, and in the long run must be- 
come virtually ineffective o 

Gonsequences of the "Law" 

In the introduction to this study we saw that Marx 
considered the falling tendency of the rate of profit to be 
the economic expression of "The barrier of the capitalist 



lo Ibid. , Po 144. 



97 



mode of production, " The "law, " Marx argued, tends to 
bring capitalist production to a "standstill" and allows 
economic progress only at the price of "periodio crisesc" 
Accordingly, the long-run consequences which Marx deduced from 
the "law" are to be understood primarily in terms of his 
theory of crises* 

The basis of this theory is provided by the "cir- 
culation schemata" of Volume II, and in particular the 

1 
model of expanded reproductiono The most general form of 

this model states that in any period net investment in 
constant capital is equal to the net product of the capi- 
tal-goods industries ("department I") less the constant 
capital consumed by the consumption-goods industries ("de- 
partment II"), AC s V, 4. s,- c^, so that /\C - V, (1 4 s*) - 
Qv^(l •» s' )t (as in the previous chapter t here represents 
the rate of turnover of the stock of constant capital, 
assumed equal to the entire capital stock). 

If, then, r is the equilibrium rate of growth of 
the capital stock, the equilibrium level of net investment 
is given by 

rC js rQ (v,4 vj(l 4- s') - v, (1 4 s' ) - Qv^ (1 4 s«)t 
It follows that there exists a fundamental rela- 
tionship of proportionality between the variable capital 



1, Of. infra. Appendix A, pp. 243-244. 



98 



flov (ioSo, the emplojnnent ) in the two departments, given 

by the ratio v, s Q (t 4 r) 
Vg^ 1 « rQ 

Since this proportion is conceived by Marx as an 
objective datum established by the path of growth histori- 
cally followed by the system. Mars maintains that the actual 
volume of Investment, as determined by the decisions of 
the capitalists, is the key variable detez^ining the ^oie 
level of economic activity* This can be expressed as a 
"multiplier" relationship between changes in net investment 
and changes in the level of employment (I standing for AC) s 

d(v. 4Va ) B g(v.4Vs.) 4 a(^. 4Va ) o dg e 1 , odg 

a I 91 "^ 9Q dl rQ(l4s') "* Q*(l4s') dl 

This can be translated into a Keynesian-type 

analysis through the implicit formula for the propensity 

to save [Y standing for net income, (v, 4v^ ) (l4s' )] given 

by the reciprocal of dY s g^^o§^ m ^ C.dg s_J.Cl-5£ ^3 

dl 91 9Q, dl rQ Q* dl rQ Q ^I 



thus 1 - rQ 

dY 1 - r!c$S 

dl ^^ 

The underlying behavioral assumption would be that 
the ex ante rate of saving (as a percentage of net income) 
reflects the past rate of accumulation and tends to in- 
crease as income increaseso 

In any case, what is Important for Marx is that 
at every point there exists a level of investment, determined 



99 



by the past growth pattern of the system, that will main« 
tain the system on its equilibrium gro^h path, and ^iiich 
is given by the equation I 2 rC„ 

If in any period I is significantly different from 
this equilibrium value the effect would be destabilizingo 
(Marx of course rejects out of hand the theory of automatic 
equilibration through the market rat© of interest.) Thus, 

if I>rC, then ?i%. Q(t4r} This relative increase in em- 
Vi-^ l-rGi 

ployment in the capitaL-goods Industries increases demand 
for consumer goods, leading the producers of department II 
to increase their investment, thereby raising aggregate 
investment still further above the equilibrium level and 
causing yet further increases in investment until some 
barrier to the process is reached. Conversely, if KrC, 
department II will be faced with insufficient effective 
demand for its products and thus will be led to contract 
its investment, causing a doimward spiral until some 
support level is found. 

Since in this model cycles are initiated by dis- 
equilibrating changes in the rate of investment, the deter- 
minants of the rate of investment are the prime movers in 
the process. It is here that Marx places his full em- 
phasis on the rate of profit s «The rate of profit, i.e., 
the relative increment of capital, is above all important 
for all new offshoots of capital seeking an independent 



100 



1 

locatloiie^ The profit rate is " the fundamental -premise 

-g . - 

and driving force of accumulation , " Accordingly, the 
occasion of a "crisis" In the Marxian model is a decline 
in the inoremental rate of profit (the "marginal efficiency 
of investment") helots the point at ^Aiich it would call 
forth an amount of Investment AC 5 rG«, 

Under the specific assumptions on which Marx de- 
rived it, would the falling tendency of the rate of profit 
be, in itself , sufficient to produce such a crisis? 
These assumptions, of course, are 1) that b^ is constant 
(i.e., that the supply of labor-power over time is in- 
finitely elastic at the given value of labor-power) and 2) 
that Q is an increasing function of the accumulation of 
capltalo In order for the amount and rate of accumula- 
tion to be determinate, given a constant s^, a further 
assumption is necessary s Investment will continue to the 
point at which the incremental rate of profit is equal to 
some given fraction of the previously prevailing ratSo 
This minimum rate of return beyond which further invest- 
ment will not be undertaken corresponds essentially to 



1. Capital , III, 30J<-. 

2o Ibld» , p, 30if, In view of these categorical statements 
it is hard to understand how Joan Robinson, on the basis of 
phrases from Volo I where the category of "profit" has not 
even been introduced, arrived at the view that Marx thought 
investment was independent of the rate of profit. 



101 



the Keynesian "liquidity trap." 

The determination of Investment in a model governed 
by these assumptions is illustrated by the following dia- 
gram, in vhich the Marginal Efficiency of Investment 
schedule is shown in reference to the prevailing rate of 
profit immediately prior to each time period and to the 
minimum profitability line p' ' corresponding to it. The 
subscripts denote time periods, not departments of pro- 
duction. 

dS 



dAC 



MEIx 




102 



MEIj represents the marginal effieleney of Invest- 
ment schedule applying in period lo p'^ represents the 
rate of profit prevailing immediately prior to period 1, 
and p"i, assumed equal to 2/3 p'l, represents the minimum 

profitability level beyond which investment cease So 

1 

Under our assumptions the KEI schedule is negative- 
ly inclined throughout, and drawn from a negative starting- 
point with coordinates p'j. and the amount of disinvestment 
required, under the assumption of a technology that grows 
steadily more capital-intensive, to maintain a constant 
organic composition of capital and therefore a constant rate 
of profit. 

The intersection of the period 1 marginal efficiency 
schedule and minimum profitability line at (A, p»i) repre= 
sents the determination of the actual investment in period 
1„ If this investment is sufficient to maintain the sys- 
tem in equilibrium, this Implies that A - rCi (Ci is, of 
course, the total capital stock of period 1)„ 

In period 2, as a result of investment during 
period 1, both the capital stock and its organic composi- 
tion have increased and the rate of profit at the start of 
the period (p'g) ^^^ decreased. Therefore the MEI 



1, I.e., that the rat^a of surplus-value is constant and 
that Q is an increasing function of capital accumulation. 



103 



schedule has shifted downward and to the left, and is now 
drawn from a starting point at p'g and the amount of dis- 
investment now required to maintain the organic composition 
of capital and rate of profit constant , 

If the minimum profitability line is maintained in 
a constant ratio to the base rate of profit (ioeo, 

^ -^ ^ ^^ the intersection of the period 2 minimum 

P^ P^ 

profitability line and marginal efficiency schedule will 

take place at (B, p"2)« 

If, however, the equilibrium growth rate of the 

capital stock has remained constant investment in period 2 

will be insufficient, since the capital stock has increased 

so that rC2^rC2 while actual investment has decreased from 

A to Bo Unless the equilibrium growth rate has meanwhile 

fallen from A to B a "crisis of underinvestment" will 

^1 ^2 
occur. 

However, it is precisely one of the implications 

of the Marxian model that a fall in the rate of capital 

accumulation will necessarily result from a falling tendency 

of the rate of profits "the rate of accumulation falls with 

1 
the rate of profit." The relationship between the rate 

of profit and the equilibrium rate of growth is determined 



1. Ibid. , 2g3o 



104 



1 

l>y dr^ s V. (Us') Thus it ie possible, through con- 
dp' (v, ^v^)s» 

tinual adjustment of the equilibrium growth rate to the 
falling rate of profit, for this model of capitalism to 
exhibit a "crisis free" evolutiono 

In this case the role of the falling tendency of 
the rate of profit as "the barrier of the capitalist mode 
of production" would be exerted through the steady decline 
in the rate of capital accumulationo This tendency to^^ard 
stagnation, following from the falling tendency of the rate 
of profit, "requires for its defeat periodical crises "J 
in either instance, despite the assumed absence of any 
technical limits to investment and the existence cf a 
positive incremental rate of profit at all levels of in- 
vestment, the capitalist economy ie unable to assure the 
uninterrupted growth of the productive forces at the ac- 
celerating rate technologically feasible. 

The actual businese=cycle theory of Marx involves 
only one fundamental change in the foregoing analysis: 
the assumption of a constant sj, is dropped. T^ether, in 
the long run, e^ tends to remain constant or to increase, 
in the course of a given cycle it is subject to substantial 
fluctuation. Consequently the incremental rate of profit 



1, Derived from vt - Q(t-Jr) through substitution fQ « s* \, 



105 



can no longer be treated simply as a function of the or- 
ganic composition of the marginal investment — the effect 
of this investment on the rate of exploitation alao must 
be taken into account,, Since at a certain point of every 
cycle the "reserve army of labor" is radically depleted, 
putting great upward pressure on wages, the shift do\mward 
and to the left of the MEI schedule at that point is not 
correlated with the factors determining the long-term 
equilibrium rate of growth, and thus cannot be compensated 
for by a decline in r, Marx, therefore, states the im- 
mediate conditions for a crisis in terms of changes in the 
rate of exploitation: 

an overproduction of capital, not of indi= 
vidua! commodities (although the overpro- 
duction of capital al-^ays includes over- 
production of commodities), signifies 
simply an over«=ae cumulation of capital. 
In order to understand what this over- 
accumulation is , , , one need only assume 
it to be absolute, Tftien would overpro- 
duction be absolute: overproduction which 
would affect not Just one or- another or a 
few important spheres of production, but 
would be absolute in its full scope, hence 
would extend to all fields of production? 



The purpose of capitalist production . o . 
is self -expansion of capital, i.e., appro- 
priation of surplus- labor, production of 
surplus- value, of profit. Thus as soon 
as capital, in proportion to the laboring 
population, would have grown to such an 
extent that neither the "absolute labor- 
time yielded by this population nor the 
relative surplus-labor- time could be ex- 
panded any further (this latter would, 



106 



moreover, not be feasible even in the case 
that the deiaana. for labor would be very- 
strong, hence a tendency for wages to rise) 
as soon as a point was reached where the 
increased capital produced no larger, or 
even smaller, quantities of surplus- value 
than it did before its increase, there 
would be absolute overproduction of capi- 
tals ioeo, the increased capital C -^ AC 
would produce no more, or even less, profit 
than capital C before its expansion by AC, 
In both cases there would be a strong and 
sudden fall in the general rate of profit, 
due to a change in the composition of 
capital on account, this time, not of the 
development of productivity but of an in- 
crease in the money-value of the variable 
capital (because of increased wages) and 
the corresponding reduction in the propor- 
tion of surplus-labor to necessary labor o^ 

It is, nevertheless, quite wrong to conclude from 

the foregoing, ae does Sweezy, that "Marx is here talking 

about a kind of fall in the rate of profit different from 

2 
that Implied in the «law««" On the contrary, only if 

the "law" is in continual operation is it legitimate to 

expect a " strong and sudden " fall in the rate of profit 

to result from a period during which the real wage had 

increased faster than the average net productivity of 

labor. The "sudden" fall in the rate of profit at the 

moment before the crisis is the combined effect of an 

increase in § and a decrease in s^. These changes, in 



1„ Capital , III, 29^ (F.L.P.H. ed,, p. 246, German ed,, 
p, 2go7I 

2, Sweezy, op, olt. , pc 152 n. 



107 



turn, are the fruit of a period in ^hlch net investment 

is at a level high enough to sustain full employment — 

and such a period is itself one of the aspects of the 

"two-faced law with the same causes for a decrease of 

the rat© of profits and a simultaneous increase of the 

1 
absolute mass of prof itSo " 

Marx's theory of the essential nature of the cycle 

as a ts^ole follows rather simply from his analysis of the 

point of crisis s 

Th© equilibrium would be restored under 
all circumstances through the withdrawal 
or even the destruction of more or less 
capitalo This would extend partly to 
the material substance of capital, o « e 
The principal work of destruction would 
show its most dire effects in a slaugh- 
tering of the values of capitals . . . 
at the same time still other agencies 
would have been at worfe» The stagnation 
of production would have laid off a part 
of the worldng-clasa and thereby placed 
the employed part in a situation where 
it would have to submit to a reduction 
in wages even below the average. 2 

Thus the depression reduces the organic composi- 
tion of the employed portion of the existing capital 
through disinvestment due to depreciation and, especially, 
to obsolescence, while simultaneously increasing the rate 
of surplus- value. Therefore a higher rate of profit 



1, Capital , III, 25g. 

2. Ibid., p, 297 (F.L.PoH. ed. , p, 2^9), 



108 



than previously realized becomes possible, (In terms of 
the previous diagram, the MEI schedule has shifted upward 
and to the right,) Meanwhile the sharp fall in the actual 
rate of profit reduces the minimum profitability criterion 
used by capitalists in their investment decisions, on the 
assumption that this criterion is based on the realized 
profit rate. (If this assumption is not justified, due 
to strong expectations of a further fall in the rate of 
profit, the capitalists may even behave perversely by 
raising their minimum profitability criterion* If that 
is the case the system is headed for collapse, ) Ulti- 
mately, in any case, the marginal efficiency of investment 
must Increase enough to generate a quantity of investment 
larger than that required by the equilibrium growth rate. 
The depression then passes its trou^ and gives way to a 
recovery. "The stagnation of production would have pre- 
pared — within capitalistic limits — a subsequent ex- 
pansion of production." These "capitalistic limits" 
manifest themselves in the fact that the falling rate of 
profit produced by a rising organic composition of capital 
and ultimately a falling rate of exploitation finally 
brings on a new crisis, "The same vicious cycle would 
occur once more under expanded conditions of production, 



1, Ibid., p. 299. 



109 



1 

With an expanded mariet and increased productive forces." 

The crucial position of the falling tendency of 
the rate of profit in Marx's economic doctrine emerges 
most clearly from consideration of the inrplications of 
the attsence of such a tendency.) If we assume that the 
additional capital AC required to maintain the "normal" 
rate of employment of the labor force will not reduce the 
previous rate of profit, henoe win itself be as profit- 
able as the existing capital stock, there is no systematic 
reason v;hy a profit-maximizing capitalism should fail to 
generate that quantity of investment o 

In euch an economy the business cycle would have 
an essentially benign character, serving merely to cor- 
rect the disproportions resulting from atomistic competi- 
tion. The economy as a whole would have no immanent 
barriers whatsoever - its expansion would be limited 
only by the availability of labor-power and natural re- 
sources. The central argument of "scientific socialism," 
that the capitalist mode of production becomes a fetter 
on the development of the productive forces, would fall 
to the ground. There might still be a case for socialism, 
but it would have to be argued exclusively on a moral, not 
an economic, basis. 



1. Ibid., p. 299< 



p,"^ no 



1 



Marx iB, therefore, quite consistent in presenting 
the falling tendency of the rate of profit as "the Tmrrier 
of the capitalist mode of production." The validity of 
his theory at this point is a necessary condition under- 
lying the claim of the Marxian system as a whole to general 
validity. 



Ill 



CHAPTER IV 



COMPARISON OF MARXIAN AND N0N-14AKXIAN 
THEORIES OF A FALLING RATE OF PROFIT 



The distinctive and salient charaoterlstiGS 
of Marx's "law" can oe brought out most clearly through 
contrast with those orthodox, or at any rate non-Marxian, 
theories which have also predicted a secular fall in 
the rate of profit© Such theories have been constructed 
along two main lines: a falling tendency of the rate of 
profit has been ascribed either to liiaitations in the 
field of physical production through the operation of 
some form of "the law of diminishing returns" or to lii&- 
itatlons in the field of realization of profits due to 
tendencies toward "undcroonsumptiono" 

Both of these approaches, in embryonic form, 

can be found in '•The Wealth of Nations •" At first Smith 

attributes the falling rate of profit simply to the 

effects of competitions 

The increase of stock, which raises wages, 
tends to lower profit, ""hen the stocks of 
many rich merchants are turned into the 
same trade, their mutual competition nat- 
urally tends to lower its profit? and when 
there is a like increase of stock in all 
the different trades carried on in the 



.\:' 



112 



same sooiety* the same competition imist 
produce the same effect in them all, a 

Shortly thereafter he specifically brings 

in diminishing returns on landj though only in passing, 

in reference to nev/ colonies: 

As the colony increases^ the profits of 
stock gradually diminish. When the most 
fertile and test situated lands have been 
all occupied, less profit can be made by 
the cultivation of what is inferior both 
in soil and situation©^ 

Finally Smith reverts to competitions 

As capitals increase in any country, the 

px'uxj.bO niixuil vsSu uc uiau.o ujr oiuyxOjrAng 

them necessarily diminish. It becomes 
gradually more and more difficult to find 
within the country a profitable method of 
employing any new capital. There arises 
in consequence a competition between dif- 
ferent capitals, the owner of one endeav- 
euring to get possession of that employ- 
ment which is occupied by another. But 
upon most occasions he can hope to Justle 
that other out of this employment by no 
other means but by dealing upon more 
reasonable terms. He must not only sell 
what he deals in somewhat cheaper, but in 
order to get it to sell, he must sometimes 
too buy it dearer. IThe demand for pro- 
ductive labour, by the increase of the 
funds which are destined for maintaining 
it, grows every day greater and greater. 
Labourers easily find employment, but the 
owners of capitals find it difficult to 
get labourers to employ. Their compe- 
tition raises the wages of labour, and 
sinks the profits of stock . . . the profits 



1. Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations , Book I, chapter 9 
(Library of Universal Literature edition. New York, 1911) > 
I, 151. 

2» Ibido . I, 157- 



113 



Which can hs made by the use of a capital 
are in this manner diminished, ae it were, 
at "both endSftl 

Smith thus seems to put his main emphasis on 
the implicitly underconsumptionist sides the failure 
of the market to expand in proportion to production is 
the assumption underlying his preposition that the in- 
creased product can he sold only "on more reasonable 
terms©" 

Ricardo^ who overlooked the "diminishing re- 

turns" aspect of Smith's theory, attacked his predecessor 

most sharply on this point? 

Adam Smith uniformly ascribes the fall of 
profits to accumulation of capital, and 
to the competition which will result from 
it, without ever adverting to the in- 
creasing difficulty of providing food for 
the additional number of laborers which 
the additional capital will employ « • • • 
Adam Smith speaks here of a rise of wages, 
but it is of a temporary rise, proceeding 
from increased funds before the population 
is increased! and he does not appear to 
see that at the same time that capital is 
increased, the work to be effected by 
capital is increased in the sam© proportion* 
Mo Say has» however, most satisfactorily 
shown that there is no amount of c&uital 
which may not be employed in a oountryi> be- 
oauea demand is only limited by production . 2 

Rioardo's own explanation, accordingly, was 
entirely based on the tendency of money wages to rise 



1« Smiths op» cit «« Bk. II, eho U', II, 38c 
2. Ricardo, Principles , p* 289, italics mine. 



114 



as essential foodstuffs 13603016 more and more expensives 

however abundant capital icay "becomej there 
is no other adequate reason for a fall in 
profit l3ut a rise of wages, and further it 
may be added, that the only adequate and 
permanent cause for the rise of wages is 
the increasing difficulty of providing food 
and necessaries for the increasing number 
of workmen»l 

This approach was essentially a simple exten- 
sion of the Rioardian theory of rents since the price 
of food is determined by its cost of production on the 
least fertile or least favorably situated land in 
oultivationj and since the increase in food produotiori 
needed to maintain the additional workers required by 
the increased capital stock ifill Involve use of lees 
fertile, higher-cost lands, the price level of all agri- 
oultraral produce, considered by Rlcardo to be the typical 
wage-good, will increase to its cost at this new margino 
The money-wage, assumed to express a subsistence real 
wage, will necessarily rise in proportion to the in- 
creased price of food^ and profits decrease by the same 

amounts 

The natural tendency of profits then is to 
fall; forj in the progress of society and 
wealth, the additional quantity of food 
required is obtained by the sacrifice of 
more and more labour • This tendency, this 
gravitation as it were of profits, is 
happily checked at repeated Intervals by 



1, Rlcardo, Princi-ples . p. 296, 



115 



the improvements in machinery, connected 
with the production of necessaries, as 
well as by discorerles in the science of 
agriculture which enable us to relinquish 
a portion of labour before required, and 
therefore to lower the price of the prime 
necessary of the labourero^ 

Ricardo's viev; of technological progress as a 
factor counteracting the falling tendency of the rate 
of profit has two essential characteristics which con- 
tinued to play the central role in post-Rioardian 
classical and neo-classical economic theory on this 
subjecto 

Most conspicuous is Ricardo's belief that 

progress in technology can merely be a partial offset 

^oheeking" the workings of a "natural tendency o" As 

John Stuart Mill, in this area a faithful disciple of 

Ricardo, rationalized this view: 

Agricultural skill and knowledge are of 
slow growth, and still slower diffusiono 
Inventions and discoveriesi tooj ocotir 
only occasionally^ while the increase of 
population and capital are continuous 
agencies* It therefore seldom happens 
that Improvement^ even during a short 
time, has eo much the start cf population 
and capital as actually to lower rent* or 
raise the rate of profits .^ 

Of equally fundamental importance is the implicit 
assumption underlying this treatment of technological 



1, Ricardo, ot?a cit ». p« 120. 

2o J» S, Mill, Principles of Political Economy (New 
York, lB6'4)t II, 30^. 



116 



changes lB5>rovement in produotive techniques is viewed 
as essentially exogenous to capital accumulationj as 
a "resisting agency," The expectation of Ricardo and 
Mill that the rate of profit will fall with capital 
accumulation thus simply expresses the opinion that the 
"forces" depressing the rate of profit, principally 
diminishing returns in agriculture, will prove to out- 
weigh those "forces" increasing it, notahly technological 
progress o 

The neo-classical economists generalized the 
Ricardian methodology and prediction into the fundamental 
proposition that a falling tendency of the rate of return 
on invested capital is the consequence of a declining 
marginal productivity of capital. This was expressed 
most categorically by J» B. Clark: 

Capital is the element that is outgrowing 
lahor. We may take the world that exists, 
instead of an imaginary one, as our illus- 
trationo As the accumulation of capital 
actually goes on, it shows itself more and 
more in qualitative changes of existing 
instruments • • • they thus represent a 
greater outlay incurred for a smaller gain » 
♦ . . Tools are^ of course, employed in the 
order of their productivity ... it soon 
ceases to he possihie to add to a working 
equipment anything that produces a multiple 
of Its own cost in a year, and the interest 
on the final increment of capital becomes a 
fraction of that capital itself. This 
fraction steadily dlminishea as the pro- 
ductive fund gro'wa larger . • • as accumula- 



1, Mill, op« clt >, II, 319. 



c\. 



117 



tlon proceeds, there are always made 
costlier machines, representing more capi- 
tal; and the product that comes from using 
them is a smaller fraction of their cost 
o . c we are utilizing the opportunities 
for investment that stand late in the 
series, and are low in the scale of produc- 
tivity » 3- 

Clark is explicitly descrihing, not the abstract 
consequences of accumulation under the assunrotion of 
static technology, but his view of the true long-run 
dynamic tendency of " the world that exists o" As with 
Ricardo and Mill, for Clark the balance of forces must 
necessarily produce a resultant tendency toward dimini- 
shing returns o 

If, however, the assumption that technology 
must progress less rapidly than the capital stock in- 
creases is challenged, the neo-olassioal analysis can 
produce no prediction as to the long-run tendency of the 
rate of profits Thus, for instance, Taussig takes a 
completely agnostic positionj 

The more * capitalistic* application of 
labor • . « may be effective at the same 
rate, or at an increasing rate, or at a 
decreasing rate. The outcome depends on 
the progress of invention, oonoerning 
whioh no rule can be laid down«2 

Accordingly, whether the rate of profit will 

rise, fall, or remain constant " depends on a race between 



la J, B, Clark, The Distribution of Wealth , pp. 183- 
186, italics minse 

2o F« Taussig, Prinoi-ples of Economics (New York, 1911) i 
II, 12o 



118 



accumula -t-.^nn ant^ jTmprovement." 

These Ricardlan and neo-classical theories 
are essentially contradictory to Marx's analysis- of the 
rate of profit. Marx criticized Ricardo on the grounds 
that, unwilling to regard capitalism as posessing an 
immanent barrier hut recognizing the existence of such 
a barrier in the falling rate of profit, he ascribes 
this tendency "not to production but to nature." Marx 
therefore rejects the duality between the "natural" 
tendency to diminishing returns and the human faculty 
of invention, the counterposition of "Increase in 
Capital'' to "Inventions and Improvements, ""^ the notion 
of "a race between accumulation and improvement." On the 
contrary, Marx maintains, "Accumulation itself, and the 
concentration of capital that goes with it, is a material 
means of increasing productivity . , . the development 
of capitalist production and accumulation lifts the 
processes of labor to a higher scale." Thus, in the 
Marxian view, accumulation of capital and increasing 
productivity are expressions of a single process. 



1. Taussig, OP. cit o. II, 2?. 

2. Capital, III, 283. 

3. J. H. Hicks, Theory of Wages (London, 1932), p. 11^. 
if. Cat)ital . Ill, 256. 



119 



The most fundamental difference between the 
Marxian and neo-olassioal theories, however, is this? 
Under the neo«olassical assunrptions the rate of profit 
will tend to fall only if the marginal physical pro- 
ductivity of capital tends to decrease «. Marx, on the 
other hand, not only does not hase his theory of the 
falling tendency of the rate of profit on the expeo« 
tation that the marginal productivity of capital Jwill 
decrease, he derives his theory on the explicit assump*- 
tion of a relationship between capital stock and output that 
can be termed a historically increasing marginal pro- 
ductivity of capital, although Marx, of course, did not 
use this concept! 

Although a machine becomes absolutely dsarsr 
with the growth of its bodily mass, it be- 
comes relatively cheaper. If five laborers 
produce ten times as many commodities as 
formerly, thiff does not increase the outlay 
for fixed capital tenfold; although the 
value of this part of the constant capital 
increases with the development of produe-* 
tivity» it does not by any means increase 
in the same proportion .^ 

In the Marxian system, a declining marginal 

productivity of capital will^ of course, produce a sharply 

falling rate of profit. What is crucial is that Marx 

deduces the same tendency of the rate of profit to fall 

on a basis vjhich admits, indeed assumes, a rising 



1, Capital s III, 305, italics mine, 



120 



marginal productivity of capital© The seemingly 
paradoxical nature of this proposition illust]?ates 
how completely the Marxian theory of the falling tend- 
ency of the rate of profit is bound up with the labor 
theory of value, under vrhich value, profit, and capital 
are strictly social terms, expressed in homogeneous unite 
of abstract labor«time, so that the increasing total 
productivity with capital accumulation implies the de- 
creasing value of the individual unit of product and the 
stability of the valae of the total net product of a 
working day of given lengths no matter how rapidly its 
mass may increase o 

Marx is sufficiently explicit on this point 
that his doctrines have seldom been interpreted in a 
decreasing marginal productivity sense « A notable ex- 
ception, hovxever, is the atten5)t of H. Do Dickinson to 
establish the validity of Marx's theory o Since Dickin- 
son makes the key assun^tion that "produet-per^head 
increases with capital-per-head but less than propor- 
tionally"^ it is, of course, scarcely surprising 
that he can claim at the end "Thus on certain broad and 
reasonable assumptions regarding the relation between 



1, Ho D, Dickinson, "The Falling Rate of Profit in 
Marxian Economies,'' Review of Economic Studies > February, 
1957. 

2» Ibid., p. 126» 



121 



the organic composition of capital and the physical 
productivity of lahor, the general correctness of Marz*s 
theory o « . appears to be demonstrated," 

Far more frequently » however, Marx's theories 
have been presented as essentially underoonsumptionist* 
Thus Keynes vie?/ed Marz as one of the inhabitants (x'Jith 
Major Douglas and Silvio G^sell) of an underoonsun^- 
tionist "underworld" in which the insights of Malthus 
were kept alive during the heyday of "classical econom- 
ics*" 

Malthus had argued that Adam Smith was on the 

right track in attributing the falling rate of profit 

to the effects of "competition*" He accepted Ricardo's 

analysis of diminishing returns in agriculture, based as 

it was on his own theory of population, but regained 

this as merely the "limiting," not the "regulating," 

factor governing the rate of profit! 

In the cultivation of land, the cause of 
the necessary diminution of profits is the 
diminution in the quantity of produce ob- 
tained by the same quantity of labor* In 
manufacture and commerce, it is the fall 
in the exchangeable value of the same 
amount of produce .2 

What in Adam Smith was In^jlicit was made explicit 
by Malthus - this fall in prices is due to the lack of 



1, Dickinson, loo» clt «, p. 129. 

2« T. R. Malthus, Principles of Political Economy (New 
rork, 1951), p. 275- 



122 



sufficient "effective demand"; 

I fiannot by any means agree with you in 
your observation tliat 'the desire of aoou- 
mulation will occasion demand Just as 
effectually ag a desire to consume' and 
that • oonsuniption and accumulation equally 
promote demando' I confess indeed that I 
know no other cause for the fall of profits 
which I believe you vrill allow generally 
takes place, from accumulation than that the 
price of produce falls compared with the 
e3Cpense of produotlon^ or in other wordSn 
that the effective demand is diminishedo 

In rejecting "Say's Law" Malthus thus made 

effective demand depend, not on production, but on a 

subjective factor, the community's propensity to consumes 

A nation must certainly have the power of 
purchasing all that it produces, but I can 
easily conceive it not to have the will©^ 

IThis *will," Malthus maintained, found its in- 
carnation in the class of "unproductive consumers^ - 
landlords, churchmen^ soldiers, government officials, 
et al p, — whose activities served only to maintain aggre- 
gate demand without adding in any way to supply? 

There must therefore be a considerable 
class of persons who have both the will 
and power to consume more materiel wealth 
than they produce, or the mercantile 
classes could not continue profitably to 
produce so much more than they consume* 3 



lo Malthus, Letter to Ricardo, in Ricardo, Collected 
Writings and Corres-pondence « VI, 132* 

2a Malthus, in ibid., p. 1^1, 

3* Malthus, Principles « p« ^0* 



125 



An squilibrium growth path, moreover, could only 

be maintained on condition of a continual increase in 

this type of consumption: 

Under all common circumstances j if an 
Increased power of production be not 
accompanied by an Increase of unpro~ 
duotive e3cpenditures J it will inevita- 
bly lower profits and throX'J labourers 
out of employment <,! 

This Malthusian conclusion is but a shade 

removed from Keynes ' dictum: 

Pyramid-building, earthquakes, even wars 
may serve to increase wealth, if the 
education of our statesmen on the prin- 
ciples of the classical economics stands 
in the way of anything better* 2 

Keynes considered the falling rate of profit an 

accomplished facts 

Today and presumably for the future the 
schedule of the marginal efficiency of 
capital is, for a variety of reasonSi, 
much lower than it was in the nineteenth 
century <> 3 

Hia explanation was, by legitimate avowal, essentifilly 

a development and sophistication of the Malthusian 

theory. Like Adam Smith and Mai thus, Keynes believed 

that as capital became "abundant" its profitability would 

have to fall: 



lo Malthus, Letter to Ricardo, in Ricardo, op» cit o« IX, 10, 

2. J, M, Keynes, G-eneral Theory of Employment, Interest 
and Money (New York, 1936), p. 129. 

3«> Ibid o , p. 308. 



124 



It is much preferable to speak of C5apital 
as having a yield over the course of Its 
life in excess of its original cost than 
as Taeing productive o . « » If capital "be- 
comes less scarce 9 the excess yield will 
diminish, without Its having becom© less 
productive - at least in the physical 
sense*^ 

The failure of effective demand to keep up with 
capital accumulation follows from Keynes' proposition 
that "the marginal propensity to consume Eie] weaker in 
a wealthy community o" One of the main factors detei^ 
mining the Keynesian Marginal Efficiency of Capital 
schedule J however, is the entrepreneurial expectation 
regarding "the strength of effective demand from time to 
time during the life of the investment under considera- 
tiono"5 Thus the tendency of the propensity to save to 
exceed planned investment continually exercises a 
depressing influence both on the profitability of exist- 
ing capital and on the marginal efficiency schedule? 

An act of individual saving means - so 
to speak - a decision not to have dinner 
today. But it does net necessitate a 
decision to have dinner or to buy a pair 
of boots a week hence or a year hencej 
or to consume any specified thing at any 
specified date. Thus it depresses 
the business of preparing today's dinner 



1» Jo M, Keynes, op« cit <,« p. 213. 
2» Ibid., p. 31. 
3» Ibid . . p. Iky* 



125 



Without stimulating the "business of 
making ready for some future act of 
consuntptiono It is not a substitution 
of future consumption-demand for pre- 
sent consumption-demand - it is a net 
diminution of such demand. Moreover, 
the expectation of future consumption 
is so largely based on current experience 
of present consumption that a reduction 
in the latter is likely to depress the 
former, with the result that the act of 
saving will not merely depress the price 
of consumption goods and leave the margi- 
nal efficiency of existing capital unaf- 
fected, hut may actually tend to depress 
the latter also»^ 

Marx has one decisive doctrinal point in common 
with Malthus, Keynes, and all other underconsumptionists • 
the rejection of "Say's Law." Thus all these economists 
are at least not blinded by theoretical "objections to 
the obvious phenomena of overproduction (phenomena 
which do not pay any attention to these objections)." 

But this is merely the posing of the issue. 
G-iven the fact of periodic overproduction, the real 
question is whether these phenomena are "cause" or 
"effect" - whether the fall in the rate of profit is 
due to tendencies toward underconsumption or, on the 
contrary, whether the periodic or even persistent failure 
of effective demand is to be explained by factors en- 
tirely within the domain of production. As we have seen, 
Marx's derivation of the falling tendency of the rate of 



1. Keynes, op. cit ., p. 210. 
2e Capital . Ill, 302. 



126 



profit on the basis that "less labor is employed in 

proportion to tbe employed capital""^ adheres strictly 

to the latter approacho The question remains? to what 

extent la the undercomsumptlonlst approach compatible 

with the Marxian model? 

Marx himself ejcplieltly rejected all the variants 

of underoonsumptlonlsm with v;hloh he xfas famlHaro Thus 

In reply to Adam Smith's explanation of the falling rate 

of profit J he stated that "the fall In the rate of profit 

calls forth the competitive struggle among oapltallstSj 

not vice-versa. To be sure, the competitive struggle 

le acconrpanled by a transient rise in wages and a re- 

2 

sultant further temporary fall of the rate of profit •" 

For the idea of "unproductive consuEptlon, " 
Marx had merely a contemptuous reference to "the phan- 
tastio idea of the priest Chalmers that the capitalists 
pocket so much more profits, the smaller the quantity 
of the annual product expended by them as capital. The 
state church then comes to their assistance in order to 
help them to consume the greater part of the surplus- 
product instead of capitalising it«"^ 

Finally, Marx made the point that if the 



lo Oapital , III, 288, 
2» Ibid., p. 301» 
3o Ibid., p. 288, 



^ s^ 127 



>^: 



phenomena of overproduction are ascribed to a distri- 
bution of income excessively skewed in favor of the 
capitalists, this is in effect an outright oontradiotlon 
of the falling tendency of the rate of profits 

Other economists, for exaciple Wakefield, 
flee to consideration of the field of 
employment ^ for growing capitals « This 
belongs in the discussion of competition j 
and is much more a matter of the diffi- 
culty for capital to realize an increasing 
profit; thus" denying the Immanent tendency 
toward a fall in the rate of profit ed 

Those economists who, like Sweezy and Joan 
Robinson, maintain that Marx was, at least in part* an 
underccnsumptionist, have no difficulty in findAng 
numerous citations j above all in Volume IIIj referring 
to the fundamental contradiction "between the limited 
conditions of consunrntlon on a c^italist basis and a 
production which forever tends to exceed its immanent 
barriers."^ But, as Mrs, Robinson is keenly aware^ over- 
production cannot be eseplained by its synonym, undercon" 
sunption. It is essential to demonstrate how tendencies 
toward underconsumption cripple the ''inducement to invest" 
and thus cause crises: 



1, In English in the original, 

g, Karl tSarx, G-rundrisse der Kritlk der polltlsohen 
O ^onomie (Rohentimrf) (Berllnt 1953) > P« 6^, cited in 
Gusten, opn cJLt»> p. 29, 

3* Capital « III, 301. 



S '■ ^ 128 



Thus to clinch the argument it is neces- 
sary to show . e . that the rate of profit 
depends, in the last resort, upon consuming 
power* It is necessary, in short, to supply 
a theory of the rate of profit "based on the 
principle of effective demand. 

This Marx fails to do, for he had mean- 
while worked out his theory of the falling 
tendency of profit, based on the principle 
of the rising organic composition of capital. 
In Volume III this theory is inextricably 
mixed up with the underconsumption theory, 
and the two lines of thought are not brought 
into any clear relation with each other. 
The theory of the falling rate of profit is 
a red herring across the trail, and prevented 
Marx from running the theory of effective 
demand to earth. 

Marx evidently failed to realize haw 
much the orthodox theory stands and falls 
with Say's Law, and set himself the task of 
discovering a theory of crises which would 
apply to a world in which Say's Law was ful- 
filled, as well as the theory which arises 
when Say's Law is exploded. This dualism 
implants confusion in Marx's own argument, 
and, still more, in the arguments of his 
successors .i 

Joan Robinson's proposition that Marx derived 

the falling tendency of the rate of profit in terms of 

"a world in which Say's Law was fulfilled" (concurred in 

u 
by (xusten - "Marx deduced the law of the falling tendency 

of the rate of profit under the assumption that Say's 

Law of Markets is valid. Although Marx was among the 

earliest and sharpest critics of this theorem, for his 

long-run theory he waived all arguments based on deficient 

2 

effective demand,") provides an approach by which a 



1. Robinson, Essay , pp. ^^-S"^' 
2c Gusten, op. cit *, p. 3o<» 



129 



clearer understanding of Marx^s relationship to 
undereonsumptionism can be gainedo 

Marx definitely assumed that, under normal 
circumstancesj capitalists would be able to realize on 
the market all the "value," including the surplus-value, 
contained in the total social product o " Periodically ," 
to be sure, "too many commodities are produced to permit 
of the realization of the value and sujrplus-value con- 
tained in them under the conditions of distribution and 
consumption peculiar to capitalist production, that is, 
too many to permit of the continuation of this process 
without ever recurring explosions o" 

But this situation is merely an aspect of 
periodic orisess one of the ways in which the "slaugh- 
tering of the values of capitals" is effected* As such 
it is strictly effect, not cause© The falling tendency 
of the rate of profit, as a fundamental long-term "law" 
of the Marxian model, applies precisely to the normal 
situation in which effective demand Is sufficient for 
the realization of all the value embodied in the 
commodity product, and not to the moments of '•periodically 
recurring explosion. •* 

Does this, however, mean that Marx in practice 
accepts Say^s Law? To answer we must be clear as to 



lo Oa-pital , III, 303» 



>0i 



130 



precisely what Say 'a Law itself means o For this purpose 

the most exact formulation is undoubtedly that of Keynes S 

The classical theory assumes, in other 
words, that the aggregate demand price 
(or proeseds) always aonoraodates itself 
to the aggregate supply price. . . o^. 

Once Say* 3 Law is correctly formulated, its 
essential difference from the Marxian assumption should 
he strikingly clear. Say's Law asserts the equality of 
an esc post magnitude, "proceeds," to an e x ante schedule, 
"aggregate supply prioso" Marx, however, states the 
identity of proceeds and aggregate value « and both of 
these are ex post magnitudes o This identity is thus of 
essentially the same nature as the Keynesian identity 
between savings and investment© 

The "aggregate supply price" schedule in Marx 
is the same as in all classical and neo-classical econom- 
Icsj the cost of production of each output plus the 
given rate of return on the capital involved^ But this 
rate of return is given as the prevailing average in 
the immediate past. If the falling tendency of the rate 
of profit is in operation, the realized rate of return 
based on the identity of proceeds with aggregate value 
must be less than this "given" expected rate of profit, 
and thus the effective demand must be less than the 



1, Keynes, opo oit »» p. 26. 



131 



aggregate aupply prio3 o 

Looked at from the angle of "effective demand" 
vjhat this means is that capitalists seek to sell their 
goods on the market for an aggregate price (in labor- 
units) that will include enough profit to allow them the 
same return on invested capital that they hare been able 
to gain in the immediately preceding period. Es hy- 
pothesi s however, tliis is excluded, since the commodities 
produced contain an insufficient amount of surplus«value© 
The capitalists would therefore have to sell their products 
for less value than they had expected to receive in 
order to dispose of them alio The products would be 
sold at their aggregate value « but this aggregate value 
is less than their aggregate price of production ex 
ante * The difference between the two aggregates will 
appear to be "deficient effective demands" 

Accordingly, far from being deduced under the 
assumption that Say's Law is valid, Marx's law of the 
falling tendency of the rate of profit is directly and 
completely contradictory to Say's Law - but in a clearly 
defined way* The rate of profit does not fall because 
there is not enough effective demand; on the contrary, 
there is deficient effective demand because the rate of 
profit is falling . The essential meaning of overpro- 
duction is "production of too many means of production 
and necessaries of life to permit of their serving as 



V ' f 



132 



means for the exploitation of laborers at a certain rate 

of profit s "^ 

Mars is therefore not at all inconsistent in 
rejecting both Say's Law and underconsumptionismo The 
basis for his critique of capitalism is not undercon- 
sumptions it is underoroduotion e "It is not a fact that 
too many necessities of life are produced in proportion 
to the existing populatlono The ^•everse is true. Not 
enough is produced to satisfy the wants of the great 
mass decently and humanely o"^ The phenomenon of 
"periodical overproduction of wealth in its capitalistic 
and self«oontradlctory form*'-^ is to Inarx essentially the 
surface sign of the underlying barrier to the capitalist 
mode of production, manifested concretely in the falling 
tendency of the rate of profit which itself testifies 
that "the real barrier of capitalist production is cap- 
ital Itselfe"^ 

The Incompatibility of underoonsumptionism with 
the main body of the Marxian system is legitimately a 
matter of slight concern to Joan Robinson, since She 



le Capital , III, 303> italics mine* 

2« Capital , III, 302© 

3, Ibid ., p. 303* 

/^. Ibid . , p. 293* 



X ry' 133 



discards the Isasio unifying principle of that system, 
quantification in units of labor-time. For Sweezyj 
who professes to accept and defend the Marxian value 
theory, this cannot be the oase» Therefore, if he is 
to bring in tinderconsuniptionisui in order to "supplement 
his EMarz's] work at a point where it is incomplete," 
this critic of Marz must, in terms of the basic cate- 
gories of the Marxian system, "demonstrate that capi« 
talism has an inherent tendency to expand the capacity 
to produce consumption goods more rapidly than the 
demand for eonsunrption goods »'* 

Sweezy seeks to prove this through the argument 
that over time a steadily increasing proportion of the 
social product tends to be invested in means of pro^ 
duction, so that "the ratio of the rate of growth of 
consumption to the rate of growth of means of production 
declines."^ He then argues that the proportion between 
the stock of means of production and the output of con- 
sumption goods tends to remain constant, so that "the 
ratio of the rate of grov/th in the output of consumption 
goods to the rate of growth of means of production reoains 
constant," and therefor© "there is an inherent tendency 
for consumption to lag behind the output of consumption 



a • o 



1« Sweezy, op» oit oi p. 180. 
2o Ibid., po I52e 



-V 



a ' 12* 



goods «"^ 

It lias been pointed out ^ several critics that 
the assumption of a constant proportion between the total 
stock of means of production and the output of consump- 
tion goods lacks any foundation whatsoever*^ More sig« 
nificantj this assumption is quite inconsistent with 
the proposition that an increasing proportion of the 
social product will consist of investment goodSo 

An analysis of Sv/eezy's attenipt at a rigorous 
algebraic "proof" of the underconsumption thesis Is 
nevertheless relevant, sines it esqposes his basic error 
much more clearly, and shows that if this error is cor- 
rected a very different conclusion emerges o 

Sweezy develops his argument on the basis of a 
model suggested by the Austrian Social-Democratic 
theorist Otto Bauer. He starts by defining national 
income per unit period of time in value terms (I) as 
made up of variable capital (w) , surplus-value consumed 
(1), and surplus-value accumulated (k). Thus 
do) 1= w-t- 1 •^ k 



1« Sweezy, op* cit «> po 183« 

2» Of. Abba P. Lerner, "Marxism and Economics," in 
Journal of Political Economy , March 19^5 i P. 83: "output 
is not the same as consumption . It includes not merely 
consumption but also the output of additions to equipment 
and to stocks of goods in process. Sweezy appears to have 
been much too dazed by the whirl of different ratios to 
notice thiSo" 



V 135 



He makes the assumption that I and all Its 
components increase steadily j that workers have a oon"> 
stant unitary marginal propensity to consume while 
capitalists' J^O is fractional and decliningj and that 
the organic composition of capital is rising ("accumu- 
lation rises as a proportion of surplus-value and 
investment rises as a proportion of accumulationo") 
Accordingly both w and 1 can be considered functions of 

(2«) w= f(k) such that 0<f»(k)<l andf'»(ls)<0 

and 
(3.) 1= 0(k) such that 0<gf»<3!:)<l and0'««(k)<O^ 

Sweezy then makes the key assumption that "the 
technically determined relation between the stock of 
means of production and output of consumption goods re- 
mains constant" so that "investment is proportional to 
the increase in consumption goods output. Hence if the 
increase in consumption in the time dt is dw + d^j, there 
will be required an addition to means of production, say 
c, such that> where A. is the factor of proportionality 



lo Sweezy, op . cit » » p« 181 « 

2, The mathematics here is somewhat sloppy, _For w and 
1 always to grow less rapidly than k, ^ and ^ should 
always be less than unitj^ry, so that ineaualiffes (2) and 
(3) should be 0<f»(k)<| and 0<^»(k)<jj^ jhis, how- 
ever, does not affect the further argument* 



136 



ik.) o= MdN •<• dl) "^ C) 

On this basis Sweezy proceeds to his demonstra- 
tion th§,t 0, ''the rate of investment required by the 
growth of consumption," must behave in contradictory 
fashion to k "the rate of investment dictated by the 
typical capitalist behavior pattern,''^ the contradiction 

do i^ dk 
to be proven by ■3=5 =v -^ 

From the previous equations, he derives 

dt" ^VdF--dt2 

and 
(60) |2i=Cf'(k)+ (2f'(k)+ 13^+ [f"(l:) *iz^"(k)lf^) 



(5«) 7?- Ax^-t;^, 



,^-^ = UX-^iS/ T 10- \X^) T XJ i^T- 1.1 • \2S.; . iw va.^ -"lat/ 



On the assumption that the absolute increase in 
national income per* unit period of time is constant or 
decreasing, 'J?<^ ' ^* follows from the above that 
(7 ) ^ ^/O 



so that 
(80) ^<o 

However it is also evident that 

"Taken together" Sweezy triumphantly concludes, 



1. Sweezy, op« eit «, p. 188 

2. Ibid. 



137 



"(8) and (9) indicate a contradiction. Capitalists tend 
to increase the rate of investment f"a;5>o) trnt the way 
they allow consumption to grow warrants only a declinlr® 
rate of investment ('rf ^^Oj," 

This "proof," alas, rests on a monstrous piece 
of confusiono Sweezy^s definitions and assumptions are 
all In value terras - "but suddenly, with equation (^)5 
he switches into " real " quantities, "means of production" 
and "consumption goods," without revealing the slightest 
awareness of what he has done; and what he has done is, 
quite simply, to make nonsense out of his whole argumento 

If the organic composition of capital is rising, 
X,9 aa the relationship between the increase in the valine 
of the output of Department II and the increase in the 
capital stock required to permit this expansion, cannot 
possibly he constant - it must continually increase ^ 
Moreover it must increase by a larger amount in every 
successive period of time under Sweezy^s assun^stion that 
"investment" rises as a percentage of "accumulation" 



(ioe., if Q, (y(^^^. B>-^ Increases with time, and i-± 



1 + j£ 

s 



1« Sweezy, op> cit .« p. 189» 

2. Therefore even in "real" terms and even accepting 
Sweezy' 8 assumption of a constant ratio between output 
and means ef uroduction, ^ cannot remain constant unless 
the proportional division of means of production between 
the sectors also remains constant, contradicting the prior 
aeeumption. 



138 



decreases with time, then _2Lj & function of the change 
in J must increase still more.) Thus dA ->Q and 

dr^ N. are necessary implications of Sweezy's own model 
andj in addition, d?\ is an increasing function of k: 

Consequently a proper analysis of Sweezy^s model 

leads to the correct equation: 

(5a) ^=\/^_«.^W f^^ 

dt /^[at^ dt^/ ^'«(k) l^dt ^ 

It is clear that ^ is not necessarily negative^ 
since the second term of the equation is always positive 
and may well have absolute value greater than the first 
term. The contradiction "proven" by Sweezy disappears, 
as was to he expected once it was revealed to be the 
simple consequence of Sweezy 's contradictory assumptions 
regarding the organic composition of capital* 

Equation (5a) in fact leads to conclusions 
very different from those claimed by Sweezy. It can 

be shown that there must exist values of Ts. such that 

dc dk 

'^*--— - « ioSo, all real roots of the equations 

dt dt 

(10,:) dl / l>-^»(3c)Lft(k) ^ gf»(k)] \ _>/A _ dgjr\ 

dt \ f«(K) -K^Mk) + 1 / '^Vdt^ dt7 
Sweezy 's method of "establishing the tendency 
to underooneumption" thus tends to prove the very opposite 
- the thesis of Tugan-Baranovsky that "given a proportional 



139 



aiBtrlbution of social production" there can be no 
general underconaumptione 

The essential point is that it is k, the actual 
investments that equilibrates production and oonsunrptiono 
The excursion into under consuroptionism serves again to 
show that, in the Marxian model, the critical factor is 
the incentive to invest a and that in this model over- 
production results from but does not cause insufficient 
investment o The strategic variables remain those 
determining the rate of profit from within the sphere of 
production-relations. Underconsumption cannot be brought 
to the aid of Marx's critique of capitalism without 
exploding hie system and substituting for it an essen- 
tially different type of economic analysis* 



1« Quoted in Sweezy, op« oit .> Pc I69. 



140 



CHAPTER V 
THEORETICAL CRITICISMS OF THE LAW 

An attack on the theoretical validity of the law 
of the falling tendency of the rate of profit from vithin 
the basic postulates of the Marxian system can he based 
on only two grounds: it can be argued that Marx was 
wrong to contend that capitalist development necessarily 
involved a rising organic composition of capital; or, 
granting that as an assumption, it can be argued that a 
rising organic composition of capital does not necessarily 
result in a falling rate of profit, since the increase in 
relative surplus -value stemming from the increased pro- 
ductivity of labor may be sufficient to compehsate for 
the increasing organic composition, producing a constant 
or even a rising rate of profit. 

In evaluating these criticisms we will begin with 
the latter. The Marxian expectation of a steadily rising 
organic composition of capital is thus to be taken, as a 
valid assumption for this part of the discussion. In 
the next stage the legitimacy of the basic proposition 
itself will be discussed. 

Relative surplus -value as compensation 
for the rise in organic composition 

As we have seen, in Marx's derivation of the 



141 



falling rate of profit the rate of exploitation is as- 
sumed to remain constant, so that: 

dt Q^(lt>s') dt 
In her critique of Marx, Joan Robinson maintains 
that this argument is inconsistent, incorrect, and at 
best tautological: 

Marx's law of the falling tendency of profits 
+-.>ien consists sj.mply in the tautology: when 
the rate of exploitation is constant, the rate 
of profit falls as capital per man increases. 
Marx can only demonstrate a falling tendency 
in profits by abandoning his argxament that 
real wages tend to be constant. This drastic 
inconsistency he seems to have overlooked. 

Marx's theory, as we have seen, rests on the 
assumption of a constant rate of exploitation. 
Certain causes which may lead to a rise in the 
rate of exploitation he treats as offsetting 
tendencies. ... To these tendencies, which 
all help to raise the rate of exploitation, 
there are obvious limits and Marx argues that 
they cannot be sufficiently strong to offset 
the falling tendency of the rate of profit. 
This may be readily admitted. But the rise 
in the rate of exploitation which comes about 
through a rise in productivity, with constant 
hours and intensity of work, and constant real 
wages, is not limited in the same way. Pro; 
ductivity may rise without limit, a nd, if real 
wages are constant, the rate of exploitation 
rises with it .i^ 

In Chapter I we showed that Marx, far from arguing 
that "real wages tend to be constant," allows theoreti- 
cally for a rising tendency of the real wage. 3 The re- 



1. Robinson, Essay , p. 36. 

2. Ibid . . p. 38. 

3. Cf. supra , ch. II, pp. 47-57. 



142 



proach of "inconsistency" is thus entirely based on the 
common misconception of Marx's theory of wages. 

Is it, moreover, justified to state that Marx's 
theory of the falling rate of profit "rests on the as- 
sumption of a constant rate of exploitation?" Mrs. 
Robinson herself recognizes, in a different context, 
that this theory is "based on the principle of the rising 
organic composition of capital. "^ On many occasions Marx 
makes it very clear that he believes his prediction of a 
falling rate of profit to be entirely compatible with a 
rising rate of exploitation. For instance, virtually at 
the beginning of his exposition, he writes: 

The law of the falling tendency of the rate of 
profit, which is the expression of the same, or 
even of a higher, rate of surplus -value, says 
in so many words: Since the aggregate mass of 
the living labor operating the means of produc- 
tion decreases in comparison to the value of 
these means of production, it follows that the 
unpaid labor, and that portion of value in 
which it is expressed, must decline as compared 
to the value of the advanced total capital. Or, 
an ever smaller aliquot part of the invested 
total capital is converted into living labor, 
and this capital absorbs in proportion to its 
magnitude less and less surplus -labor, although 
the proportion of the unpaid part of the em- 
ployed labor may simultaneously grow as com- 
pared with the paid part.^ 

Marx is therefore neither inconsistent nor tauto- 
logical - the crucial point, however, is whether he is 



1. Robinson, Essay, p. 50. 

2. Capital . Ill, 252. 



143 



correct in claiming that increases in the rate of ex- 
ploitation resulting from the higher productivity of 
labor cannot systematically raise the rate of exploita- 
tion enough to compensate for the increase in the organic 
composition of capital. 

Sweezy charges that this claim is completely 
unfounded : 

If both the organic composition of capital 
and the rate of surplus -value are assumed 
variable, as ve think they should be, then 
the direction in which the rate of profit 
vill change becomes indeterminate. All ve 
can say is that the rate of profit vill fall 
if the percentage increase in the rate of 
surplus-value is less than the percentage 
decrease in the proportion of variable to 
total capita l.l 



1. Sveezy, ov. cit .. p. 102. In his ovn formulation of 
the question Sveezy falls into hopeless confusion. His 
definition of the organic composition of capital is 

q = c and the rate of profit p' = s'q' (q»=l— q = r^J 
^ ofv °*^ 

This is, on its face, meaningless since the symbols used 
stand for f lev variables, and the rate of profit is based 
on the stock of invested capital. But in any case it is 
impossible to make sense of the formula q' » 1 — q, since 
the algebraic operation can be performed only if c-fv is 

c*v 
identically equal to unity, and as ve have seen this can 
never be the case, since the tvo "v's" represent different 
quantities: the v" in the numerator stands for the living 
labor-pover entering into the commodity-product, while the 
"v" in the denominator represents merely the infinitesimal 
"stock of variable capital." 



144 



It is not possible to demonstrate a falling 
tendency of the rate of profit by beginning 
the analysis with the rising organic compo- 
sition of capital. 1 

Marx, of course, was veil aware of this objection, 
and attempted to answer it. His refutation was based on 
the existence of an absolute limit to the amount of 
surplus-value that any given number of workers couM 

produce: 

To the extent that the development of produc- 
tivity reduces the paid portion of the em- 
ployed labor, it raises the stirplus- value by 
raising its rate; but to the extent that it 
reduces the total mass of labor employed by 
a certain capital, it reduces the numerical 
factor by which the rate of stirplus -value is 
multiplied in order to calculate its mass. 
Two "laborers, each working twelve hours daily, 
cannot produce the same mass of surplus-value 
as 24 laborers each working only two hours, 
even if they could live on air and did not 
have to work for themselves at all. In this 
respect, then, the compensation of the reduc- 
tion in the number of laborers by means of an 
intensification of exploitation has certain 
impassible limits. It may, for this reason, 
check the fall of the rate gf profit, but 
cannot prevent it entirely. '^ 



1. Sweezy, op. cit ., p. IO5. Though Maurice Dobb, more 
than Sweezy, is concerned about demonstrating his ortho- 
doxy, he comes to substantially the same conclusion: 
"That [Marx] provided no a priori proof that one set of 
influences would dominate the other was an omission which, 
I believe, was . . . made advisedly because it would have 
been alien to his whole historical method to suggest that 
any answer could be abstractly given." (Political Eco^omy 
anri Haoitalism [New York, 19^0], p. 109). 

2. Capital . Ill, 290. 



145 



\7 



Marx uses an extreme example, and, moreover, an 
unclear one, since he does not state whether the two 
hours worked by each of the 24 laborers represents their 
surplus working time or their total working time (and if 
the latter, at what rate of surplus -value are they work- 
ing? Do they also "live on air^'?)o 

His basic point, nonetheless, is a simple one 
and quite plausible. The rate of profit is a ratio be- 
tween two co-ordinate variables, surplus -value per man 
and capital invested per man. The first of these has 
an "impassible limit" - the duration of the working day. 
The second, however, has no finite limit - in a com- 
pletely automated economy it would approach infinity. 
As the two variables approach their limits the ratio be- 
tween them must therefore approach zero. 

Glisten considers that "this argument is faulty" 
because Marx "constructs a linear relationship between 
the increase in productivity and the increase in surplus - 
value. ""^ This "linear relationship," however, was in no 
way implied in the foregoing citation which says nothing 
at all about the relation between increases in produc- 
tivity and s imp lus- value. The weakness is nevertheless 
a real one: even though there must always be a potential 
increase in Q, large enough to decrease £i whatever the 



1. Giisten, op. cit ., p. 40 » 



146 



change in sj_, It does not follow that as g, increases to 

this value pj. must fall steadily and syst ematically. 

Marx's basis for expecting this steady fall was 

stated most explicitly in a passage from the rough draft 

of Capital ; 

The greater the surplus -value appropriated hy 
capital because of the augmented productivity 
... or the smaller the already established 
fraction of the working day which provides an 
equivalent for the workers, so much the smaller 
is the increase in s\irplus -value which capital 
can obtain from an increase in productivity. 
Surplus-value increases, but in ever diminish- 
ing proportion to productivity. To the extent 
that capital is already developed ... so much 
the more frightfully must it increase productiv- 
ity even to expand (i.e., to increase surplus - 
value) by a lessened proportion - because its 
barrier always remains the proportion between 
the fraction of the day which expresses neces- 
sary labor and the entire working -day. Only 
within these boundaries can it move.-'- 

Rosdolsky maintains that this argument is suffi- 
cient to establish Marx's contention, and Gilsten essen- 
tially agrees with him, with the proviso that "the rate 
of profit must finally fall . . . previously, however, 
the rate of profit can also rise over time, since while 
the rate of surplus -value is lo\f, s\irplus- value increases 
with relative speed. "^ (i.e., if the real wage is con- 
stant and s'< 1 . a given percentage increase in produc- 
tivity will cause a more-than-proportional increase in 



1. "Grundrisse," p. 2^6, cited in Rosdolsky, "Zur Neueren 
Kritik des Marxschen Gesetzes der Fallenden Profltrate," 
Kyklos . 1956, p. 221, 

2. Gtisten, op. cit ., p. 46. 



147 



siirplus -value o ) 

Even here, however, the argiment is seriously in- 
complete, since it relates the increase in surplus-value 
only to the increase in productivity and not to the in- 
crease in the organic composition of capital required to 
bring it about. Since, however, Marx assumes in effect 
that the "marginal productivity of capital" is an increasing 
function of capital per man (ioe., that productivity 
increases more than proportionally with organic composi- 
tion), s\irplus -value can increase less rapidly than pro- 
ductivity while maintaining the same proportion to 
capital . The essential problem can only be solved on 
the basis of the explicit functional relationship between 
surplus -value and organic composition . 

This relationship must be conceived strictly in 
the long-run sense, abstracting completely from all short 
and intermediate term fluctuations. In other words, we 
must start with a dynamically stable model, whose para- 
meters are assumed to remain constant over timeo 

The variables of the system, then, are; 

g - The organic composition of capital 

s_^- The rate of exploitation 

2].- The rate of profit 

TT - The index of net labor-productivity 

w - The index of real wages 

t - Time 



NJ 



148 



Its parameters are given by the following basic 

assumptions: 

(1) Labor -productivity is Increasing continually 

and at a constant rate 

(2) Relative changes in productivity have a con- 
stant and more than proportional relationship to changes 

in the organic composition of capital (i.e., 'Mt'the elasti- 

EQ 

city of 17 with respect to Q, ' is constant and exceeds unity.) 

(3) Relative changes in the real wage have a 
direct, constant, but less than proportional relation- 
ship to changes in labor -productivity (i.e., iE is con- 
stant, positive, and less than unity). 

Thus the.se parameters are 



r = 


loge Jt 
^t-1 


u : 


sir^i 

EQ-^ 


fe = 


^ (0<b<l) 

ETT 



Prom the assumption u = HT can be derived the 

EQ 

equation expressing productivity as a function of organic 
composition: 

u = nr - M-S , Tr=T(Q) 

EQ dQ T 



M = u'"'(0-) r= fuZM dQ 

dQ Q - V Q 



1. a, of course, is the constant of proportionality based ^ u 
on the value of Tf arbitrarily chosen when t = (i.e., a = _£ ) 

''o 



149 



This is Marx's long-run "production function," in 
which changing technology is the primary determinant of 
changes in productivity and must involve under capitalist 
conditions the change in social relationships expressed 
hy a rising organic composition of capital. Because it 
is based on technological change it is irreversible - at 
every point in time £ is concGived as having a unique 
and determinate value. 

Given the values of r, u, and b, and the values 
vhen t = of sj. and 2* the value of EJ. at every point of 
time is determined. 

If s'o s^ and Qq = 9,- then To » ae^ and, since 

si, surplus- labor is equivalent to s urplus product , 
necessary^laDor necessary product 

IL 1, then Wo « a©}^ 

^ l+(f 

At every time t it follows that 



and 



oau ^ t)rt 
W4. = s-P.. ■ P 
t li-cr ^ 



1. This in no way implies that Marx's short -run model 
involves "fixed coefficients." The contrary is the case. 
Every single machine has its own unique implicit organic 
composition/' depending on the value originally invested 
in it; its age, deterioration, and obsolescence; and the 
amount of labor required for its operation. Which of 
these machines are used to bring about short-run changes 
in production is determined through the market. 



150 



Accordingly the rate of exploitation, s't , is 

determined by a9^(lt.^)gi:J: _ l 

aeu g brt 



s't = (1+Oe^^-^^^^ - i" 



Similarly the organic composition of capital, 
Qt, is determined by /e^e-"'^ 



Qi 






From the basic formula for the rate of profit, 
it foliovs that 



^ Q(i->-g-)e ^t(u^i-buj . 

From this it is easy to derive the rate of change 
of 2l ^■■t every point in time _ 

.,. ■ M-.un...e(i-b)rt^ait.)eU-^)^t^i] £^g;m 

dt 9 (i.,o.)gr, t(u-hl-bu) 



dgj r- r[.u('l"'b^ 



[I 



dt 



u9d+a-)££iiiillz^ 



It is evident that the condition for a falling 
tendency of the rate of profit, ^<0 , ^^ simply 

1— b^ 

The conclusion of this analysis is that, despite 
Sweesy's discovery that "It is not possible to demonstrate 
a falling tendency of the rate of profit by beginning the 



151 



analysis with the rising organic composition of capital," 

Marx vas completely justified in his derivation of a 

falling rate of profit from a rising organic composition 

of capital. When Marx vrote it was generally accepted 

as an empirical fact that the rate of profit had tended 

to fall: accordingly it was legitimate to assume that 

the inequality ?..'- > u already prevailed. Since b and 

1— h ^ 
u are parameters of the system, changes in this inequality 

depend on changes in si. But if s • is to decrease over 

time this requires that b>'l, so that d^J. must always he 

dt 

negative, while if s' increases the inequality must in- 
crease. 

Consequently Marx's prediction of a falling rate 
of profit is the necessary expression of his basic pro- 
position: that the rising organic composition of capital 
is " but another expression for the incre ased productivity 
of labor . "•*• It is thus the tendency of the organic compo- 
sition, not of the rate of exploitation, that is the de- 
cisive theoretical test of Marx's argument. 

Must the organic composition of ca pital increase? 

Since, from a theoretical standpoint, the falling 
rate of profit depends entirely on the rising organic com- 
position of capital, the crucial argximents against Marx's 
theory are those which challenge the rising tendency of 



1. Capital . Ill, 253. 



152 



the organic composition. 

The starting point of these criticisms is that 
Marx merely proclaims that Q must tend to rise, hut pro- 
vides no reason vhy this must be so. Thus Hans Peter 

writes: 

The increase of Droductivity must no¥ come to 
expression in the rise of Q. No reasons vill 
he given for this proposition - it will merely 
he continually repeated.-^ 

Marx himself, moreover, seems in at least one 
place to admit that this is the case: 

Considered abstractly, the rate of profit may 
remain the same, even though the price of the 
individual commodity may fall as a result of 
an increase in the productivity of labor and 
a simultaneous increase in the number of these 
cheaper commodities, for instance, if the in- 
crease in the productivity of labor extended 
its effects uniformly and simultaneously to all 
the elements of the commodities, so that the 
total price of the commodities would fall in 
the same proportion in which the productivity 
of labor would increase, while on the other 
hand the mutual relations of the different 
elements of the price of commodities would 
ren^in the same. The rate of profit might 
even rise, if a rise in the rate of surplus - 
value were accompanied by a considerable re- 
duction in the value of the elements of con- 
stant, and particularly of fixed, capital. 
But, in reality, as we have seen, the rate of 
profit will fall in the long run.^ 

Giisten's reproach to this passage can hardly be 
disputed: 



1. H. PfttftT^. Elnfiihrung in die ool itische Okonomie» 
Stuttgart, 1950, p. 106, cited in Gtlsten, PPt cit»> P* 2b n. 

2. Capital , III, 269 (German edition, p. 258). 



153 



But this casual remark, 'as ve have seen,' is 
not correct since, as Peter rightly observed, 
only the continually repeated assertion of a 
rising organic composition is to be found in 
the foregoing sections. At the decisive moment 
in his argument it ill becomes a theoretician 
of Marx's stature to appeal to 'reality' as 
against 'abstract consideration, '•'■ 

The essence of the matter is stated clearly by 



Gilsten: 



In the long run Q vill increase only if pro- 
ductivity in the producer goods industries 
increases more slovly than capital intensity 
(a technical composition) .^ 

The crucial problem, to which Marx failed to 

give a systematic solution, is therefore to show the 

immanent necessity for a rising tendency of the ratio, 

in "real" terms, between means of production and net 

output . 

Marx's attempts, mainly in Theorien iiber den 
Mehrwert . to demonstrate such a tendency, amounted es- 
sentially to the contention that the increase of pro- 
ductivity in the sectors dependent on nat\iral conditions, 
such as agriculture, lags behind the increase of produc- 
tivity in industry. 

Giis ten's critique of this line of reasoning is 
conclusive: an argument based on such a "lag" is itself 
subject to all the argtmients raised by Marx against the 



1. Giisten, op^ cit ., p. 56. 

2. Ibid ., p. 52. 



154 



Rlcardlan theory of the falling rate of profit, notably 
that it constitutes a "flight from economics . . . into 
organic chemistry."^ Moreover, even granting this lag, 
the organic composition of capital will not increase un- 
less the increase of productivity in those sectors is 
also less than the increase of technical composition in 

them . 

Does this, however, mean that Giisten is justified 
in writing that since Marx "admits in somewhat concealed 
fashion that this evolution Ltechnical progress] need not 
lead to a rising organic composition if the increase of 
productivity is everywhere equivalent . , . therewith 
collapses the thesis that the rise in the organic compo- 
sition is 'but another expression for the rising produc- 
tivity of labor '"?2 

This judgment is valid only if it can be shown 
that "neutral" technological progress, in the sense of a 
constant ratio between means of production and output, is 
a theoretically possible case in the Marxian model. -^ 
Though Marx, as we have seen, nowhere presents a proof 
that technological progress under capitalism must be 
"capital-using" rather than "capital-saving" or "neutral," 



1, Grundrisse, p. 639, cited in Gtlsten, 02.i_cit., p. 58. 

2, Giisten, op. cit ., p. 59. 

3 Non-neutral progress of the "capital- saving" variety 
cannot be possible if neutral progress is itself impossible , 
("Means of production" here denotes only fixed capital.) 



155 



he at least indicates two lines of argument which can 
serve to establish this crucial point. 

The first of these, which Giisten develops ex- 
tensively in a different context, his discussion of 
Joan Robinson's theory of economic growth,-^ rests on 
Marx's theory of the role of the industrial reserve army. 
The existence of the "s\irplus laboring population" is, 
according to Marx, "a condition of existence of the capi- 
talist mode of production."^ The reserve army is neces- 
sary to capitalism because without it no rapid expansion 
of production would ever be possible without creating a 
situation of over-full employment in which wages woulxd 
rise so rapidly as to reduce surplus -value: without the 
reserve army, a capitalist economy would continually come 
up against what Joan Robinson calls "the inflation barrier." 
Thus the industrial reserve army is "the pivot upon which 
the law of demand and supply of labor works. It confines 
the field of action of this law within the limits ab- 
solutely convenient to the activity of exploitation and 
to the domination of capital."-^ 

What, then, are the implications of "neutral" 
technological progress? It is immediately evident that 



1. Giisten, op. cit ., chs. VII -X. 

2. Capital , I, 693. 

3. Ibid . 



156 



if the organic composition of capital is constant, the 
capital stock cannot grow faster than the lahor force. 
There can be no reserve army in this situation ^ since as 
long as additional workers are available there will be 
no barrier to Increased investment. 

The essential point is that "neutral" techno- 
logical progress creates a full-employment situation in 
which there are irresistable pressures for a rapid in- 
crease in wages. Even aside from the ability of orga- 
nized workers to enforce wage demands in these circum- 
stances, unless wages were rising so fast that profits 
and savings were reduced to a level consistent with the 
rate of growth of the labor force, the high rate of 
profit would stimulate a ratio of savings (5 investment) 
to capital stock greater than this labor force growth 
rate. 

In this situation, with wages tending to rise and 
profits to fall, it is obvious that every entreprenexor 
will seek to substitute capital for the "scarce" factor, 
labor. This "substitution," of course, is realized 
through investment - the "innovations" chosen for reali- 
zation will be those most labor-saving. In this way 
technological progress ceases to be "neutral" and becomes 



1, Of. Hicks, OP. clt .. p. 125. While "autonomous" in- 
ventions, according to Hicks, are random and therefore 
on balance neutral , "induced" inventions tend to be 
labor-saving . 



157 



labor-saving, causing the organic composition of capital 

to increase. 

It is therefore surprising that, after develop- 
ing this argument vith enormous thoroughness, Giisten 
concludes that it gives no support to Marx's theory of 
a riding organic composition of capital hecause it 
"assumes an alteration in the relative factor-prices and 
thereby is excluded as an explanatory factor in relation 
to the law of the profit rate." 

It is precisely because the alteration of "rela- 
tive factor -prices" is the necessary consequence of 
neutral technological progress that it provides support 
for Marx's theory: this is what demonstrates that the 
capitalist economy has an inevitable bias, that economic 
growth tends to be shunted off the neutral and on to the 
capital-using growth path. 

The second line of argument whereby a rising or- 
ganic composition of capital can be derived on a Marxist 
basis is a logical one, starting from the assumption, 
which Gtlsten claims leads to "collapse" of the rising 
organic composition thesis, that "the increase of produc- 
tivity is everywhere equivalent," 

The point, as stated earlier, is to show that 
the technical composition of capital must tend to in- 



1. Giisten, on. cit ., p. 139. 



158 



crease faster than the productivity of labor. As we 
have seen, both technical composition (means of produc- 
tion per man) and lahor -productivity (net real output 
per man) are ratios in vhich the numerator is expressed 
in real terms (i.e., as a quantity of use -values) and 
the denominator in value terms (i.e., as a quantity of 
lab or -time) . 

The productivity of labor is the net mass of 
use -value produced divided by the living productive 
social labor required for its output. The technical 
composition of capital is the mass of use-values accumu- 
lated in the form of means of production, divided by 
the amount of living productive social labor required 
to set them in motion. This, in effect, is how Marx 
uses these categories when he writes that the value- 
increase of constant capital " nur entfernt das Wachstum 
der wirkllchen Masse der Gebrauchswerte darstellt . " 

If these two ratios were independent ♦ there would 
be no reason why technical composition had to increase 
more rapidly than labor- productivity. But in fact the 
two are not independent. 

The use-value of a capital - good is composed of 
two aspects: it Is required for the production of 
things . and at the same time it is required for the pro- 



1. Das Kapital . Ill, 239. Cf . ch. I, supra , pp. 21-23. 



159 






duct ion of relative sur plus -value . Its utility is there- 
fore a combination of its capacity-i ncreasing effect and 
of Its labor -savins: effect. 

We can therefore assume that, as long as any- 
extra labor is available, the use-value of a capital- 
good will increase proportionally with its capacity, 
assuming no Increase in the productivity of labor - two 
identical machines will have twice the use-value of one. 
Now if use-value were only determined by capacity, the 
movement of technical composition and of labor-produc- 
tivity would be identical: if capacity were doubled and 
labor input increased by 50^, both ratios would be rep- 
resented by iOQ. = 1.333. . . • Since, however, a machine 
150 

of given capacity has more use-value insofar as it permits 
a higher productivity of labor, the use- value of the new 
machine will be more than 200, and consequently the tech- 
nical composition of capital will exce ed l.:^33 . . . , 
the index of labor productivity. 

This logical demonstration that technical compo- 
sition must increase more than proportionally with labor- 
productivity confirms Marx's contention that, in his 
model, the increased organic composition of capital "is 
but another express ion f or the incre ased productivity of 
labor " and that therefore it is "a logical necessity" of 
the development of the capitalist mode of production "to 
eive expression to the average rate of surplus-value by 



160 



a falling rate of average profit." 

Summary 

\lha.t has been accomplished in this chapter has 
heen to establish the theoretical validity, given the 
postulates and assumpt^ions of his system, of Marx's 
derivation of the "Lav of the Palling Tendency of the 
Rate of Profit." The rising tendency of the organic 
composition of capital has been shown to be bound, as 
a " logical necessity ." to the increasing productivity 
of labor, and a falling rate of profit has been shown 
to follow inescapably from a rising organic composition 
of capital. 

¥e thus will be working with two concrete and 
empirically verifiable predictions generated by the 
Marxian model. If the Marxian system is to uphold its 
claim to general validity as the basis for any scientific 
understanding of society and of history it must be able 
to withstand the empirical test of these predictions. 



161 



CHAPTER VI 



CALCULATION OP THE ?AARXIAW RATE OP PROFIT, RATE OP 
SURPLUS -VALUE, AND ORGAOTC COMPOSITION OP CAPITAL: 
THE UNITED STATES, 1900-1960, (CURRENT DOLLARS) 



Basic Procedure 

In accordance with the interpretation of the 
Marxian definitions presented in the first part of this 
study the rate of profit has been calculated as the ratio 
between aggregate net surplus -value and the capital stock ; 
the rate of surplus -value as the ratio between aggregate 
net surplus -value and aggregate variable capital ; and the 
organic composition of capital as the ratio between 
the capital stock and the sum of surplus -value and var- 
iable capital o All these were computed on the basis of 
the aggregate non-farm private business economy. Since 
in Marxian terms government (both general and non-profit 
government enterprises) and private households, inasmuch 
as they employ no productive labor-"- and therefore pro- 
duce no sTJTpl-us -value, are "non-capitalist" sectors of 
the economy, investment in and property income origi- 
nating from these sectors were excluded from the com- 
putation. In this stage of the computation the basic 
variables for each year were calculated as quantities 



1, Cf. supra ch. II, p, 59 • 



%i^.. 162 



of ourrent dollars . 

Gapltal Stoolg 

The denominator of the rate of profit and 
numerator of the organic composition of capital, the 
capital stock, was defined by Marx as the value, netoof 
depreciation, of the physical capital Involved in the 
total production and circulation process. This stock 
has been computed as the aggregate of producer durable 
equl-pment » structures , inventories a and fuel and mineral 
reserves in the capitalist sect ore It was derived as 
the cumulated net investment in each category of capital 
assete 

To express capital and depreciation in current 
dollars a price-index based on the consumer purchasing 
power of the dollar was used* This was necessary since 
the existing price-indexes for capital goods, based 
essentially on labor and materials costs, do not fully 
account for improvements in the quality of capital goods 
produced, and thereby overstate the actual increase in 
capital-goodfl prices over a long period. Deflation of 



1«, Of. Go Terborgh, Sixty Years of Business Capital 
Formatlon « VJashington, 19dO (Mimeographed supplement > 
pp. 2-^)! 

"the customary deflation of capital expend- 
iture figures by the available indexes of 
plant construction costs and equipment 
prices is unreliable and misleading. 



;« • • e 



163 



capital expenditures by a consxiinption p2?ice~index gives 
a value of the capital stock expressing the current price 



So far as we can make out, the available 
indexes of equipment prices reflect changes 
in prices per unit of equipmen'^ , o » this 
might be worth having if the so-called 
pieces were the same from year to year, but 
as everyone knows most items of equipment 
are constantly being iniproved in performance 
and efficiency* . . . Not even this much can 
be said for the indexes of plant construc- 
tion costs o Since each structure is unique, 
it is impracticable to price units of output 
(finished construction). What the indexes 
price is units of input (materials and site 
labor) e Obviously this approach makes no 
allowance for inrprovements in productive 
efficiency in the construction operation it- 
self. The omission gives the index an added 
upward bias over and above the bias it shares 
with the index of equipment prices. . . . 

o , « Insteadj we measure changes in 
real investment from year to year, this being 
defined as investment in dollars of constant 
purchasing power. This differs from the 
usual deflation by the substitution of an 
index of the general purchasing pov^er of the 
dollar for the indexes of specific capital 
goods prices discussed above, . . , We use 
throughout as our deflator the broadest avail- 
able measure of changes in the purchasing 
power of the dollar, the "iioplicit" deflator 
for the privately produced gross national pro- 
duct, computed by the Department of Commerce." 

This conclusion, however, is Illogical, 
The "implicit" deflator for private GNP is 
actually a weighted average which includes 
the capital goods deflators that have been 
judged "unreliable and misleading," The only 
consistent procedure is to reject these in- 
dexes altogether, and rely only on the 
Personal Consumption Expenditures deflator as 
a measure of "the general purchasing power of 
the dollar," 



164 



equivalent of the purohaslng-power originally "frozen" 
in the shape of capital goods (or, in neo'^olassical 
terms, the original "saorifioed consumptions'') Instead 
of a direct estimate of current reproduction costo 
"viewed from another angle, the value derived in this 
way can he considered the hest approximation to repro- 
duotton cost, given the assumption of equal rates of 
productivity change in hoth capital-goods and consumer- 
goods departments o 

In the computation of capital coneun^tion, the 
"double-rate declining balance" method was used, as the 
most realistic of the various conventional methods of 
depreciation accounting*, 

Surplus-value 

Marx defined surplus-value as the share of the 
national income (net of capital consul^ ti on) available 
for consumption and investment by the capitalist class, 
£i«e., after-tax net property income (profit. Interest, 
and rent) originating in the capitalist sector»io In the 
present computation the capitalist sector was subdivided 
into oori3orate and non-corporate sectorSo For each, 
surplus-lvalue was computed gross of nominal depreciation 
and other capital charges. Net profit was determined by 



1. Cfe G-. Terborgh, Realistic Depreciation Policy ^ 
Machinery and Allied Products Institute, Washington, 195^j 
pp. 1^9-153 • 



165 



subtracting estiniated actual ooneumptlon of capital 
from the oorablned gross surplus-value of the two sub** 
sectorsj after this oomhined gross-surplus-value was 
adjusted for the nori'-produotive governmental espenditure 
paid for through direct taxes on nominal property income* 

The non-corporate stream of gross surplus-value 
was derived in the following way; 

'She total income of uninooirporated husinesseSj 
composed of income of unincorporated snterpriseSj inven** 
tory valuation adjustments and charged depreciation, was 
reduced Twr the incomes of farmers, financial interme- 
diaries, and professional practitioners » To the quantity 
thus determined were added estimated net interest and 
net rent originating in the same sectors » Finally, 
from this aggregate v/ere deducted the revenues ascrihahle 
to labor seirices of proprietors engaged full-time in 
their own businesses, as estimated on the basis of the 
average annual earnings of full-time employees in each 
industry* The quantity thus derived represents surplus** 
value gross of depreciation and of direct personal taxes 
originating in the non-corporate sector. 

The exclusion of the Finance, Insurance * and 
Real Estate industry group was necessary to avoid double 
counting, since to the extent that net profit in this 
sector originates in the area "of the economy included in 
this study it is already accounted for as net rent and 



166 



1 
net interest flowing from the other sectors. Pro- 
fessional practitioners were excluded under the assumption 
that the totality of their net income represents pay- 
ment for their o^m labor services* 

In the determination of corporate gross surplus- 
value a similar procedure was followed, again excluding 
Agriculture and Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate o One 
additional component xms included: salaries of corporate 

officers, who are considered hy Marx as capitalistSa 

2 

recipients of surplus-value » Rent from both corporate 

and non-oo27porate sectors vta-B taken net of estimated 
real-estate taxes© 

Aggregate gross surplus-value was arrived at 
by deducting from these Income streams the estimated 
portion of them paid as direct taxes imposed upon individ- 
ual recipients of surplus-value o The final step in the 
computation of net profit was simply to deduct estimated 
actual capital consumption from ag^egate gross surplus- 
value o 

Variable Capital 

Although surplus-value is defined by Marx as net 
property income originating in the capitalist sector, 
he defines variable capital, not as net labor income 



1. Theoretically, a portion of the value of office build- 
ings, etc. used by these industries, corresponding to the 
excluded income, should be deducted from the total capital 
stock. This however, was not attempted since an accurate 
estimate was impracticable. 

2. Of. supra , ch, II, p» 68. 



157 



originating in that sector but as that portion of net 
labor income received by productive laborers alone « 

Productive laborers, as shown earlier j isere 
defined as those employees in the capitalist sector 
whose work is part of the process of actual production 
of oomnjodities; in contradistinction to those workers 
whose functions, though socially necessary in present- 
day society, are involved in administration and distri- 
butions but do not contribute to physical production of 
goods and services* 

G-ross variable capital, accordingly, was confuted 
as the portion of total en^loyee compensation in the 
commodity-producing industries of the capitalist sector 
( Agricultural Services. Forestry- and Fisheries , Mining , 
Manuf aottir ing « Qonstruotion a Transportation a Oomniuni- 
cations . Public Utilities , and Services) received by 
the productive laborers enrol oyed In each industry* 

Net variable capital was derived by deducting 
from gross variable capital the estimated portion of it 
paid as direct taxes by individual recipients of labor 
income « 

The Basic Batios 

Once the current-dollar values of the capital 



le Cf. supra . ch» II, pp. 57-61, 



168 



Stock* variable capital, and surplus-value have been 
calculated,, the fundamental ratios of the Marxian system 
( organic composition of capital a rate of profit s and 
rate of aurolus-'value ) are directly given© 

This calculation, however, differs from the 
strict Marxian concept of these ratios in one fundamental 
respects it is carried out in current prices through a 
price-index relating the money value of the national 
income to the sum of use-values making up t he national 
income and noi to the quantity of productive labor'^time 
required to produce those use-values <, In other words, 
it is based on calculations in terras of purchasing power 
over units of final consumption, and not over units of 
factor input o 

It is clear that the deflator used to determine 
the current dollar value of capital stock and deprecia- 
tion as measured by a "labor-value" index will increase 
more rapidly than the deflator measured by a "use-value" 
index? precisely to the extent that the net productivity 
of labor increases , since the index of the net produc- 
tivity of labor is simply the ratio of the two denomi** 
nators: national income in use-values over the labor- 
value of the national income. 

Therefore, to the extent that the index used to 
translate the original cost of fixed capital into the 
current-dollar total needed to determine the portion of 



169 



gross income that actually represents capital consumption 
rises less rapidly than would a "lahor-value" Index, to 
that extent the current value of the capital stock and 
the amount to he deducted from gross surplus-value as 
depreciation are less than would he the case if a 
"lahor-value" index was used» Ratios computed on the 
basis of these totals must give a biased image of their 
"true" Marxian correlatives. Thus, as against their 
values under the strict tlarxian definitions, the rate of- 
profit and rate of surplus-value will show an upward, 
and the organic composition of capital a downward, bias, 
all increasing with time (insofar as net productivity 
tends to Increase with time)o 

Calculation in these terms, nevertheless, is 
entirely relevant to the Marxian model. It is, in fact, 
necessary, in order to estimate the strength of the most 
important "counteracting cause" resisting the workings 
of the "Law of the falling tendency of the rate of profit"? 
the effect of increasing labor net productivity in in- 
creasing the purchasing power of gross surplus-value. 

I/esplte the desirability, from a social-account- 
ing viewpoint, of taking induced obsolescence into 
account as a real cost of investment through a labors 
value concept of capital consumption, it may realistically 
be hypothesized that the investment behavior of entre- 
preneurs will reflect their expectation of return on 



^>v 



170 



investment in units of final purchasing power rather 
than of labor-time* Thus, even if a falling tendency 
of the rate of profit were found to exist in lahor- 
value terms, this tendency eould scarcely have the 
drastic consequences Marx ascribed to it unless it 
also became manifest in terms of the values that are 
immediately related to capitalistic motivations, ioOo, 
in terms of a purohasing-power concept of investment 

and profitability.. 

Accordingly, the preliminary hypothesis to be 

tested is this: 

As computed in terms of a pricc'^index based on 
consumption purchasing power* the Marxian rate of profit 
in the U. 3, non-farm economy will show a significant 
tendency to decrease over the period 1900-1960 «, 

Invalidation of this hypothesis would not in 
itself refute Marx's theory, but it would cast substan- 
tial doubt upon his conclusions from the theory* 

Results 

The fundamental ratios and the current-dollar 
quantities of surplus-value, variable capital, and the 



^/ > 171 



capital stocfc for each year from 1900 to i960, as 
calculated according to the procedure just desorlued^ 
are given in Table I and presented graphically (to semi- 
log scale) in Charts I and II o Summary data on which 
Tahle I is based are presented in Appendix Bo 

The trend of the rate of profit over the entire 
period was computed on the basis of a regression with 
the rate of profit as the dependent, and time as the 
independent, variable o All years in the period were 
used, except for the years of deep depression (1931*" 
1935) and of the second World War (19^1-19^5) « 

On a linear basis, this regression is 

p» = 13,0570- •1083t (t counted from 1900) 
with correlation coefioient r = -•8053 

On a logarithmic basis the regression is 

log p« = 2,57669 - .0l085t 
with correlation coefficient r = -.8021 



172 



Chart VI-1. 



Rate of Profit and Organic Composition 
of Capital (inverted). 1900-1960 
(Ctirrent Dollar Basis) 



Scml-Loavlthmlc oW HOS tfH 

2 Crdca X 10 to the Inch 




173 



Chart VI-2. Rat© of Profit and Rate of Surplus- 
Value, 1900-1960 (Current Dollar Basis) 




2 Crdcs I 10 to the Inch 



'■•^: •:* 



174 



Tatle VI-1, 



Fundamental Rati (as, I90O-1960 (Millions of 
Current Dollars) 



TeT 



( 



"TfT 

'3T2I 

3o00 
2o86 
3ol2 
2o83 

3»03 
3o28 

3»07 
2.83 
3o02 

3.23 
2.9^ 
3.29 
3»17 
2o90 
3.28 

3.73 
3o76 
3.29 
3.91 
3*93 
3.25 
3^52 
3.4^ 
3o23 
3060 
3.30 
3»22 

7.08 
7.06 
i|..68 

3.^3 
3.12 
3o76 
3.50 
3.13 
2.71 
2*36 
2ol0 
2,03 

2.27 



Year 



— (ir~ 

Variable 
Capital 



(b) 
Surplus- 
Value 



(c) 

Capital 
Stook 



TIT 

s« 

ilL 



1900 


4328 


3055 


1 


4750 


2993 


2 


5130 


3444 


3 


5569 


4176 


^ 


5^58 


3453 


5 


6116 


3949 


6 
7 


6879 


3889 
4329 


8 


5866 


4328 


9 


6892 


4214 


1910 


7521 


5512 


11 


7^5 


4986 


12 


8I31 


4485 


11 


8690 


5564 


8009 


5202 


^ 


8i^l3 


5688 


16 


10572 


6792 


17 


126iK) 


6754 


18 


15986 


5013 


19 


18288 


6451 


1920 


22679 


10420 


21 


16332 


8873 


22 


16830 


6639 


11 


21153 
20121 


8757 
8536 


25 


20731 


9907 


26 


2215^^ 


11684 


27 


22013 


8547 


28 


22178 


11401 


29 


23151 


12366 


1930 


19467 


10008 


31 


15177 


5411 


32 


10978 


826 


i2 


IO8I6 


230 


13593 


3772 


35 


15053 


5381 


36 


17697 


7102 


37 


20975 


8II5 


38 


16802 


7100 


?9 


I8I79 


7200 


19% 


20546 


8897 


41 


27760 


10719 


k2 


37836 


12646 


43 


46413 


14057 


ifif 


48085 


16I89 


45 


44428 


14899 



23677 
24514 
25708 

27913 
27808 

28440 
30797 
33945 
33392 
34063 
36820 
37704 
40785 
41851 
43450 
44729 
50296 
63661 
78306 
93058 

98533 
92176 

97239 
100894 
105434 
109220 
110092 
110967 
114219 
111484 
98092 
83598 

77937 

8I313 

82557 

85023 

90898 

89939 

88707 

92293 

104171 

119108 

126698 

130529 

134577 



I 



70o59 
63.01 

67*13 
74a99 
63o26 

64o57 
59ol4 

62o93 
73.78 
6I0I4 
73.29 
66.61 
55.16 
64.03 
64.95 
67.61 
64.25 

53.^3 
3I036 
5el7 
5o95 
54.33 
39.45 
41.40 
42.42 
47.79 
52.74 
38.83 
51.41 

53.^1 
51.41 

35o65 

7.52 

2.13 

27.75 
35.75 
40.13 
38.69 
42,26 
9.61 
3.30 
38061 
33 ^42 
30.29 
33.67 
33o54 



^ 



12.90 
12o2l 
13.40 
14.96 
12.42 
13.89 
12.63 

12.75 
12.96 

12.37 
14.97 
13.22 

11*00 
13.29 
11.97 
12.72 

13.50 

10.61 

6.40 

6.91 

9.58 

9.01 

7.20 

9.01 

8.46 

9.40 

10.70 

7.76 

10.27 

10.83 

8.98 

5.52 

.99 

.30 

4.64 

6.52 

8.35 

8.93 

7.89 

8.12 

9.64 

10.29 

10.62 

11.09 
12.40 

11.07 



175 



Year 



19^ 
^7 

^8 
^9 
1950 
51 
52 

53 
5^ 
55 
56 
57 
58 

i960 



(a) 
Variable 
Capital 



(b) 

Surplus- 
Value 



Capital 
Stock 



46060 


12319 


153762 


S^kzz 


13255 


I86I5I 


59090 


21692 


212080 


55232 


18^35 


2204'38 


6202if 


18689 


235590 


71787 


21519 


267667 


75^73 


21399 


287680 


8I278 


20892 


302882 


77163 


21200 


3l6o48 


83938 


28^7^ 


331251 


89116 


272^1-5 


35854^ 


913^5 


27^12 


389315 


86538 


21276 


9^350 
97^9 


30079 


1^23721 


30597 


2fi^56l6 



JUL 



26*75 
2ii'«81 

36071 

33o38 

3O0I3 
29o98 

28e35 

25 a 70 

2?»i!'7 

33o92 

30»57 
30.01 
29.21 
31.88 
31.39 



TiT 
ill 



8,01 

7.12 

10.23 

8.36 

7.93 

S^Oil- 

7«4^ 
6o90 
6.71 
8«6o 
7.60 
7.0i^ 
60I9 
7.10 
6.87 






2.63 

2o79 
2*63 

2o99 
2o92 
2o87 
2.97 
2,96 
3«21 

2.95 
3.08 
3o28 

3«65 
3.i^l 
3o48 



Souroes! 

Column a (Variable Capital): Appendix B, Table VII, 

Column b (Surplus-value): Appendix B, Table VI. 

Column c (Capital Stock); Appendix B, Table II. 

Column d Cs* (rate of surplus-value)] Column b 
divided by Column a. 

Column e Cp' (rate of profit)]: Column b 
divided by Column 0. 

Column f [Q (organic oon^osition of capital)]: 
Column divided by Column a plus Ooliuan b. 



176 



Sour CSS and Methods 

The statistical sources used were: 

U.S. Department of Conimerce; National Income^ 
1929-1953, U.S. Income and Output , Survey of Cui-rent 
Business, July 1962 (which continues all scries taken from 
U.S. Income and Outout through I960 - all references here- 
after to U.S. Income and Output should be considered to 
include reference to the July 1962 Snrvey of Current 
Bu siness for the years 1956-1960), Historical Statistics 
of the U.S., Colonial Tines to 1957 j and Statistical 
Abstract of the U.S., 1962 o 

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics; Employment and 
Earnings (BLS Bulletin 1312) 

U.S. Departments of Labor and Coinmerce; Construction 
Volume and Costs, 1915-1956 and subsequent issues of 
Construction Review 

U.S. Internal Revenue Service; Statistics of 

Income ( annual ) 

U.S. Bureau of the Census; Census of Manufactures 
195I|- and 1958 , and Census of Mineral Industries, 1958 

R» Goldsmith; A Study of Saving in the U.S. 

Jo Kerdrick; Productivity Trends in the U.S. 

Go Terborgh; Sixty Years of Business Capital 

Formation 

S, Kuznsts; National Income and Its Composition 

Ro Martin; National Income in the U.S., 1799-1938 



177 



Ao Capital Stock 

1. Price Indes (Appendix B, Table I)o The price 
index used to express capital stock and depreciation in 
current dollars was, for I929-I960, the G-ross National 
Product Personal Consumption Expenditures Deflator ( U. So 
Income and Output . Table VII-2, p* 220) linked in 1929 to 
the Bureau of Labor Statistics Consumer Price Index 
( Historical Statistics , Table EII3, p« I76) and in I913 to 
the Snyder Cost of Living Index as given by Goldsmith 
( Study of Saving . Vol. I, Table T-I6, p. 377) o 

2o Producer Durable Equipment (Appendix B, 
Table II, col, a) « For the period 1929-I960 non-farm 
private purchases of Producer Durable Equipment were 
estimated as the residual after deduction of farm PDE pur- 
chases as estimated by the Securities and Exchange 
Commission ( U. S. Income and Output » Tables V-3 and V-9, 
pp. 190, 19^ J and National Income, 1929-1953 . Tables 6 and 
31, pp. 166, 208, extended to 1929 by Table 32, p. 210) 
from total private purchases of Producer Durable Equipment 
( U. 3. Income and Output . Table I-l, p. 118). For the 
period 1899"*1928 the figures used are those given by 
Goldsmith ( Study of Saving, Vol. I, Table P-5, p. 877). As 
Goldsmith's estimate of business investment In passenger 
automobiles is considerably below that of the Office of 
Business Economics, his estimate of this component for 
1900-1928 was increased by the percentage necessary to 



178 



equalize aggregate PDE expenditures according to the two 
concepts in 1929, The initial estiraate of the stock of 
Producer Equipment at the end of 1928 was taken from 
Goldsmith ( Study of Sa ving, Vol. Ill, Table ¥-1, p. lit-) 
reduced by the percentage of agricultural equipment in 
this stock, as given in Historical Statistics , p, 1^2. 

Gross investment in producer Equipment was broken 
down into groups of different average life-expectancy on 
the basis of the percentage breakdown implicit in 
Goldsmith's figures for 1900-19^5, projected to 19514- on 
the basis of U.S. Income and Output , Table V-5, p. 192o 
Since the QBE has not continued this series beyond 195'4-» 
the percentage breakdown used for 1955-1960 was that of 
total expenditures for the period 19l!.7-195l4-o 

3, Business Structures (Appendix Bg Table II, 
col. b)o Investment in business plant was taken as the 
sum of the following seven series of private structures 
put in place: Industrial , Office & Warehouse , Store, Res- 
taurant & Garage , Miscellaneous Non-residential , Public 
Utility , Hon-house keeping. Residen tial, and All Other Private 

structures 

These series, for the period 1915-1960, were 
taken from Consti^uction Volxme and Costs, 1915-1956 
( Supplement to Construction Review , 1957) and subsequent 
volumes of Constructi o n Review » They were extended back 
to 1900 by the estimates given by the Machinery and 



179 



Allied Products Institute in the statistical notes 
supplementary to Sixty Years of Business Capital Formation , 

The stock of business structures at the end of 
1899 was taken from Goldsmith ( Study of Saving , Vol. Ill, 
Table ¥-1, p. lli). Business plant was depreciated, as 
by Goldsmith, on the basis of a 50 year life-span, 

i|.. Fuel and Mineral Development Expenditures 
(Appendix B, Table II, col, c) . Expenditures for mining 
development for the period 190O-I96O were estimated as 
by Goldsmith as yfo of the value of coal and minerals 
extracted, and x^rere taken from Study of Saving , Vol. I, 
Table R-l5> Po 6OI; Historical Statistics , pp. 350-351; 
and Statistical Abstract of the U.S., 1962 , pp. 712-713 o 
They were depreciated, as by Goldsmith, on the basis of 
a I4.O year life-span. 

Oil and Gas Vfell Drilling expenditures for 1900- 
19I4.5 were taken from Goldsmith ( Study of Saving , Vol. I, 
Table R-lIj-, p. 6OO) and, for 19^6-1960, from U.S. Income 
and Output , Table V-3, p. 190, They were depreciated, 
as by Goldsmith, o'n the basis of a 25 year life-span. 

The initial value of each series was derived from 
1899 expenditures on the basis of the average ratio of 
capital stock to gross investment for Producer Equipment 

in 1899. 

5, Inventories (Appendix B, Table II, col, d) „ 
The aggregate value of non-farm business inventories at 



180 



the end of 19^0 "was taken from National Income, 1929-1953 y 
p. 1360 This total was cumulated forward and backward by 
the sum Net Inventor;/ Change less Inventory Valuation 
Adjustment as given for 1929-1960 in U.S. Income and 
Output , Table I-l, p. II8 and Table 1-6, p, 126, and, 
for 1900-1926, by Goldsmith ( Study of Saving , Vol, I, 
Table P-19, p. 903). 

Bo Capital Consumption (Appendix B, Table III) 

Capital Consumption for every category of depreciable 
asset was calculated on the basis of the life-spans used 
by Goldsmith ( Study of Saving , Vol. I, Table P-7, p. 878) 
which he, in turn, took from the Internal Revenue Service 
Bulletin F, 19ij-2 o Depreciation on each component of the 
capital stock in a given year was calculated by dividing 
the value in current prices of that component at the 
star'^. of the year, plus l/2 the gross investment for that 
year, by l/2 the average life-span. 

The method of computation of capital consumption and 
of the mid-year value of each component of the capital 
stock is shown in Exhibit A , which gives the computation 
of the stock and depreciation of aggregate biisiness 
structures for 191+8 and 19lj-9o 

Co Total Gross Surplus-Value 

la Corporate Gross Surplus-Value (Appendix B, 
Table IV) o Gross surplus-value originating in the 



181 



corporate sector was estimated as the sum of Corporate 
Book Profits , Inventory Valuation Ad.fastment . Officers' 
Salaries , Net Interest . Met Rent , and Capital Charges 
(including depreciation charges and capital investment 
charged to current expense)©, 

(a) Corporate Book Profits ; For 1929-1960 total 
after-tax corporate profit (including depletion charges) 
Xv'as taken from U.S. Income and Output . Table 1-12, p. 13!^, 
reduced by after-tax profit in the Agriculture and Finance , 
Insurance, & Real Estate sectors as given in U.S. Income 
and Output , Table VI -7, pc 20^, and Rational Income, 1929- 
12i3, Table 20, This series was extended back to 1921 
^y Statistics of Income totals and to 1900 on the basis 
of the estimates of corporate net profits given by- 
Goldsmith ( Study of Saving . Vol. I, Table C-5, p. 917). 

(b) Corporate Officers' Salaries ; for 1929-1960 
corporate officers' salaries were taken from U.S. Income 
and Output , Table 1-12, p. 13!^, less officers' salaries 
in the Agriculture and Finance, Insurance^ & Real Estate , 
sectors as given in Statistics of Income . For 1919-1928 
all these totals were taken from Statistics of Income . 
The series was extended back to 1900 on the basis of net 
corporate dividend payments for the previous year as 
estimated by Martin, National Income in the U.S., 1799- 
1938 , Table I3, p. l).2o 



182 



(c) Met Interest ; For 1926-1960 corporate net 
interest was taken from Statistics of Income total net 
interest payments by non-financial, non-agricultiiral 
corporations. This series was extended to 1919 on the 
basis of Statistics of Income figures for total interest 
paid by these corporations, and to 1900 on the basis 

of interest paid by manufacturing corporations, as given 
by Goldsmith ( Study of Saving , Vol. I, Table C-13, p. 925) o 

(d) Net Rent ; For 1933-1960 corporate net rent 
was taken from Statistics of Income total net rent and 
royalty payments by non-financial, non-agricultural 
corporations, extended to 1929 on the basis of Statistics 
of Income figures for total rent and royalty receipts by 
the Finance, Ins'orance, & Real Estate sector. The whole 
series was reduced by the ratio of non-income taxes paid 
to rent received for Real Estate corporations, as given 
annually in Statistics of Income e This final series was 
extended to 1900 on the basis of net rental payments 
from rrianufacturing industries, as estimated on the basis 
of census figures by Martin, 

(e) Capital Charges ; Depreciation charges by 
non-financial, no n- agricultural corporations for 19i|.6-1960 
Xr/ere taken from U.S. Income and Output , Table VI-18, p, 216, 
For 1900-19i|-5 total corporate depreciation charges as 
given by Goldsmith ( Study of Saving , Vol. I, Table C-tj.1, 

p« 955) were reduced by the percentage of tax depreciation 



183 



taken by the agriculture and financial sectors, as given 
annually for 1919-1945 in Statistics of Income , and 
estimated for years between 1900 and 1918 as the 1919- 
1921 average of this ratio. 

Capital outlays charged to current expense were 
taken as the total oil and gas -well-drilling and mining 
development expenditures shown in Table B II, col. c, 

(f) Inventory Valuation Adjustment ; Corporate 
non-farm inventory valuation adjustment vas taken from 
U.S. Income and Output , Table 1-8, p. 126, and Study of 
Saving . Vol. I, Table P-19, p. 903. 

2. Unincorporated Business Gross Surplus -Value 
(Appendix B, Table V) . Gross surplus-value originating 
in the unincorporated-business sector (i.e., all unincor- 
porated business vith the exception of the Farm . Finance , 
Insurance, & Real Estate , and Professional sectors) was 
estimated as the sum of Proprietors Income . Inventory 
Va lua t ion Ad.ius tment . Net Interest . Net Rent , and 
Depreciation Charges , less the Wage -equivalent for the 
work of proprietors working full-time in their own 
business. 

(a) Proprietors Income : Income of unincorporated 
enterprises for 1946-1960 was taken from U.S. Income and 
Output . Table VI-4, p. 202, and, for 1929-1945, from 
National Income. 1929-195^ . Table 1?, p. 182. This sum 
was reduced by Finance, Insurance, & Real Estate income, 
and by the income of Farm and Professional proprietors. 



184 



estimated as a percentage of their respective sector totals 
by interpolation between and extrapolation forward from 
the benchmark estimates for 1929, 1939, and 191^-5 given in 
National Income, 1929-19^3 , p. 77 on the basis of the 
percentage division of National Income within each sector 
as shovn in U. S, Income and Output , Table I-IO, p. 130<, 
The series was extended back to 1900 on the basis of the 
estimate of entrepreneurial income in these sectors given 
by Martin, National Income in the U. So. 1799-1938, Table 

10, p. 39o 

(b) Depreciation Charges ; Non-corporate depre- 
ciation charges for 19i|.6-1960 were taken from U. S, Income 
and Output , Table VI-19, p. 217o This series was projected 
back to 1900 on the basis of estimates of depreciation 
charges on unincorporated business commercial and industrial 
structures and producer durable equipment given by Gold- 
smith ( Study of Saving , Volo I, Tables R-10, R-13* P-12, 

and P-13, PPo 595, 599, 891, 693.) 

(c) Net Interest ; Net interest from unincorporated 
business was estimated on the basis of "Net Interest from 
Sole proprietorships and Partnerships" as shown in U. S, 
Income and Output , Table 1-12, p, 131^-, extended to 1900 

on the basis of the estimate of net interest received by 
individuals given in Martin, opo oit o. Table i|., po 21o To 
derive the net interest component for each year these 
estimates were multiplied by the ratio of Proprietors Income 



^ 



185 



in the sectors covered to total Proprietors Income. 

(d) Met Rent ; Net rental payments from the 
covered sectors of unincorporated business for 1959 were 
taken from Statlstios of Income for that year, the first 
in which these figures have been glveno On the assumption 
that rental payments from wholesale and retail trade in 
1929, as derived in Martin, op> cit o. Table 33, p« 79, 
from the 1930 Census of Business , were evenly divided 
between corporate and non-corporate sectors, net non» 
corporate payments in that year v/ere estimated by apply- 
ing the 1959 ratio between total net rent from the 
sectors covered and total rental payments from the unin- 
corporated wholesale and retail trade sect ore This 
estimate xms projected back to I900 on the basis of 
Martin's estimate of total rent from wholesale and re« 
tail trade, and forward to 1959 on the basis of net cor- 
porate rent from wholesale and retail trade, as shown 
in Statlstios of Income . The I960 figure was estimated 
by projecting the average annual increase for the pre- 
vious two years 6 The tax ratios previously derived for 
corporate net rent were applied to the entire series. 

(e) Inventory Valuation Adjustment ; Inventory 
Valuation adjustment for I929-1960 was taken from U« S« 
Income and Output s Table 1-8, po 126, and, for I9OO- 
1928, was taken from Goldsmith ( Study of Saving < Vol. I, 
Table P-19, p» 903.) 



186 



(f) Wage-Qgulvalent s The number of proprietors 
engaged In full-time work in each industrial sector for 
1929-1960 v/as derived by subtracting "?\ill Time Equivalent 
Employees" aa given in U. Sa Inco me and Output t» Table 
VI-13, p, 211 and National Income. 1929-1953 . Table 25, 
p» 196, from "Persons Engaged in Production" ["This 
aeries measures man-years of full-time employment by 
persons working for wages or salaries (as shown in Table 
71-13) ^J^d by active proprietors of unincorporated 
enterprises"] given in U» S<. Income and Output s Table 
VI-16, p, 21^ and National Income, 1929-1953 . Table 27, 
p* 202. This series was projected back to 1900 on the 
basis of aggregate private non-agricultural employment 
(taken from Historical Statistics , ppo 73 and 75). The 
aggregate wage-equivalent was determined, for I929-I960, 
by multiplying the number of proprietors engaged in full- 
time work in each sector covered by the average annual 
wage in that sector, as given in II« 3. Income and OutT?u tj 
Table VI-I5, p. 2I3, and National Income. 1929-1953 . 
Table 27, p« 200, and, for 1900-1928, by multiplying 
the estimated total number of full-time working proprie*- 
tors by the average private non-agricultural wage, as 
projected back from I929 on the basis of the wage indexas 
compiled (for 1919-1923) by Kuznets and (for I90O-I9I8) 
by Douglas, as given in Historical Statistics of the 



1. U, S« Income and Output , p. 21^« 






187 



3o Direct Taxes on G-roas Surplus-value (Appendix 
B, Table VI) « For I917-I960 direct taxes paid out of 
gross surplus-value were calculated on the Tmsle of the 
estimated effective tax rate paid by upper-bracfeet in- 
come recipients* This rate was estimated^, on the basis 
of the figures given in Statistics of Income , by 
dividing total tax paid by total income for those re- 
tixrns extending to but net including the bracket contain- 
ing the return V7ith rank, cumulated from the top, equal 
to 5% of total "Persons Engaged in Production - Private 
Industries" as given for 19'lj'6-196o in U» So Income and 
Output . Table VI-I5, p, 21^, for 1929-19^5 in National 
I ncome. 1929-19 '53 . Table 28, p. 202, and, for I917- 
1928, in Eendrlck, Productivity Trends in the U. S. . p, 306, 

The effective final rate of taxes on gross 
surplus-value xiras determined by multiplying this Federal 
Income Tax rate by the ratio between total ( Statistics 
of Income ) income tax payments and all other Federal, 
State, and Local personal tax payments, as given for 
1929-1960 in U^ S. Income and Output o Tables III-l and 
2, pp. 16^5, and National Income, 1929-1953. Tables 
8 and 9, extended to 1917 on the basis of Kendrick, 
op. clt ». Table A-II-b, pp. 296-7 • 

The portion of gross surplus-value subject to 
tax was determined by deducting from total gross surplus- 



\\r~ 



188 



value the sum of capital charges (estimated as above), 
inventory valuation adjustment (estimated as above), and 
undistributed corporate profits, as given for 19i*'6-196o 
in U. So Income and Output . Table VI-9, p. 20? > and, for 
1929-19^5 in National Income, 1929~1953 » Table 22, ex- 
tended to 1919 by the estimate of corporate net saving 
in Kuznets, National Income and Its Oomposition , Table 
22, and to I917 by the estimate of corporate net profit 
lees dividend payments in Martin, National Income in 
the U. So . p. ^'2o 

The series of total direct taxes paid on gross 
surplus-value was extended back to 1900 by the estimate 
of total personal tax payments in Kendrick, op. oit ». 
Table A-II-bo 

Do Variable Capital (Appendix B, Table VII) 

lo Total employee compensation for each industry 
group ( Manufacturing . Mining « Construction . Transpor- 
tation, Eublio Utilities and Communications , Seryloes, 
Agricultural Seiryises, Forestry, and Fisheries ) was taken 
from U, 3. Income and Output . Table VI-I, po 200, and 
National Income. 1929-1953 . Table 1^, for I929-I960, 
extended back to I919 by the estimates given in Kuznets, 



1, After exclusion of en^jloyee compensation for employees 
of households, professionals, and non-profit enterprises. 



)^ ' 189 



opo Glt o, TatJle 50 9 and to 1900 by the estinstes given 
in Martin, ox>e cit * 

2, Gross labor income originating from each 
Industry was estioiated by deducting from total employee 
compensation the corresponding total of corporate officers 
salaries as given for 1919-1960 in Statistios of Income 
and extended back to 1900 by the previously derived series 
of aggregate officers* salaries (with the exceptions 
of the Servioes and Transportation^ Oommuni oat ions, and 
Public Utilities groups, for which Statistics of Income 
cautions that its pre«1929 figures are seriously incom- 
plete and for whlehj therefore, it was the 1929 estimate 
of gross labor income itself that was extended back by 
the Kuz-nets and Martin series ») 

3« Gross productive^labor income was obtained 
by multiplying gross labor income by the estimated per- 
centage of it received by productive laborers. In the 
specific industries this percentage was derived as 
follows s 

(a) Manufacturing ; The Census of Ifenufaotures 
definition of "production-related worker" is virtually 
identical to the Marxian definition of "productive 
laborer o" Accordingly, the percentage of labor income 
received by productive laborers is indicated by the per- 



le Cfo supra t cholls pp» 60-51 • 



190 



oentage of total payroll (excluding corporate officers' 
salaries) shown in the Census as received by production 
workers© This percentage is given in the 1958 Oensus 
of Manufactures , Vol. I, pp. 1-3, for the years 1899, 
190^, 1909, 191^, 1919, 1921, I923, I925, I927, I929, 
19 33 J 1935, 1937 » 1939, 19^7 s and annually from 19^9 to 
19580 For other years between 1919 and i960 the per- 
centage of income received by productive laborers was 
estimated by interpolation on the basis of the ratio, of 
^production workers" to "all employees," as given in 
the BLS Bulletin 1312 » Employment and Earnings , For the 
period 1900-1919 it was estimated by linear interpolation 
between the benchmark figures given by the Census ♦ 

(b) Transportation; Communications and Public 
Utilities; Services; and Agricultural Services , Forestry « 
and Fisheries S In the absence of either census or survey 
data on the percentage of production workers in these 
industry-groups, the percentage of production-worker 
income determined for manufacturing was used to estimate 
gross productive-labor income originating in them, 

(c) Mining s The 1958 Census of Mineral Industries , 
Vol. I, pp. 1-^, gives data on the percentage of pro- 
duction workers and production-worker wages for the years 
1902, 1909, 1919, 1929, 1939, 195^* and 1958. Using the 
percentage of labor income received by production workers 



^;.\ 



191 



in those years as benchraarks, this percentage for other 
years was determined, for 19^7-3-960, by Interpolation 
on the basis of the ratio of production workers to all 
employees given in Employment and Earnings and. for 
1900-19^5 by interpolation on the basis of the per- 
centages previously determined for manufacturing* 

(d) Gonstruction g Employment and Earnings 
shows, for 19^7-1960, the number of "construction work- 
ers" and of "all employees" in the constraction industries© 
For these years the percentage of labor-income received 
by productive laborers v/as derived by multiplying the 
percentage determined for manufacturing by the ratio 
between the number of productive laborers (as a pro- 
portion of all employees) in Construction and in 
Ifenufaoturing, ae given by Employment and Earnings o The 
series was extended back to 1900 on the basis of the per- 
centages previously determined for manufacturingo 

^o Direct taxes on variable capital^ for 1929« 
i960, were estimated on the basis of the average tax 
rate applying to all but the upper brackets «> This rate 
was determined by deducting uppei?-bracket total income 
and federal income tax paid, (as already calculated to 
determine the tax rate on gross surplus-value) from, 
respectively, total personal income (as given in U. .3<» 
Income and Output t Table II-l, p» 1^) and total Statistics 



192 



pt Income personal incom© tax payments, then dividing 
this residual tax by the residual income* 

As in the case of direct taxes on gross surplus- 
value, the effective final rate of direct taxes on var*- 
iable capital was determined by multiplying this federal 
income tax rate by the ratio of total personal tax pay« 
ments to federal income tax payments » 

The 1929 rate of taxation of variable capital 
was extended back to 1900 by the series of total per« 
sonal tax payments as a percentage of G-NP taken from 
Kendriok, pp» cit «» Table Afll-'b* 

Evaluation of Data 

The reliability of data in all the statisticsal 
series diminishes as they go back tov/ard 1900, and is 
clearly much Icwer for the early years* For the period 
since 1929 all series except net rent from unincorporated 
business are taken directly from estimates by the Office 
of Business Economics and the Internal Revenue Service 
which are judged by these sources to be the most reliable 
available, and from Census and Bureau of Labor Statistics 
data. 

For the pre~1929 period the quality of estimates 
ranges from fairly reliable, in the case of wage data 
and of most statistics from the corporate sector (with the 
exception of net rent,) to highly unreliable, in the case 



193 



of noi>*oorporat« gross surpluS'-Talue* Oonsequently* the 
pFe»1920 estloates should be taken essentially as in- 
dloating the general order of magnitude of the rate of 
profit9 rate of surplus-value* and organic oonposition 
of oapital in that period. 

As an approximation of this sort, ths pre-1920 
data are fairly satisfactory. This measure of oonf idenee 
is based on the faots that even txie least reliable 
estimates have no evident bias in either direotlwn* 
that the genez«l level of all ratios is quite stable 
throughout the entire pre-war period, and that the fluo- 
tuations in the x«te of profit conform to the kncwn 
oyolioal pattern^ Ths seeming anomaly of the steep 
decline of the rate of profit in the years 1918-1919 i> 
to be explained hy the rapid incirease in money wages 
(almost 50ji over the two years), the institution of 
significant income taxation for the first time, and the 
substantial negative inventory valuation adjustment due 
to sharp price increases* 

The general trend of the rate of profit emerging 
from these data tends strongly to confirm the hypothesis 
tested. The computed regressions show a clear and 
statistically significant tendency of the Marxian rate 
of px>ofit to decline over time* This tendency is shown 
most strikingly by simple coBQ>arison of the 1929 rate of 



194 



profit J iloOO;^j to the 6«87/^ achieved In the most 
recent peak year, 196O0 

The trend of the organic composition of capital 
is not as strongly marked, but is also upward over the 
entire period, even after the spectacular fall in World 
War II o In i960 its value was 3oi|^, against 3»20 in 
1929 and 2o86 in the earliest peak year, 19036 

The rate of surplus-value, concerning which Marx 
provided no systematic basis for prediction, shows a 
major decline over the 60 years, contrary to Marx's 
expeotationo 

Exhibit A g Aggregate Business Structures, 194^8-19^9 * 
(Colo b in ^, all others in $ millions) 

rear (a) (b) (0) . jd) , ( e) (f) . . (g) 

19^ 69492.8 105*79 735l6oi^ 6030 306le3 76W5.I 75000 08 
19if9 762f85«l 99^1 7580^ai^ 5721 31^06 7837808 77091o6 

Explanation 

Cole as Value of aggregate structures at end of previous 
'~ year (col* f for previous year.) 

Col« bj Price-index for current year divided by price- 
*" index for previous year*, 

Ool© s? Initial value of structures for current year 
" (col* a multiplied by col* b) • 

Col* ^^: G-ross Investment in business structures during 
current year* 



4\ I 196 



Colo e; Value of capital consumption for current year 
"" (col, c plus 1/2 colo d divided by 25s ^^^^ 
the as'sumed 50-year average life span for 
business structures.) 

OoId fs Terminal value of structures for current year 
"" (colo c plus oolo d minus colo ^)o 

Colo ^2 Average (raid-year) value of structures for current 
year (colo c plus colo f divided by 2)o 



196 



CHA.PTER VII 



G/^LCUIATION OF T'^E MARXIAN RATE OP PROFIT, RATE 
OP SURPLUS-VALUE, ORGAl^IIC COMPOSITION OF CAPITAL, 
mD NET PRODUCTIVITY OF LABOR: THE UNITED STATES, 
1900-1960 (LABOR-VALUE UNITS) 



Basic Procedure 

Computation of the rate of profit, rate of surplus- 
value, and organic, composition of capital in strict 
accordance -with. Marx's concepts requires that the basic 
categories of his system (variable capital, surplus-value^ 
capital consumption, capital stock) be calculated in terms 
of the basic quantitative ujn.it of the Marxian system: the 
hour of socially necessary labor-time ^ 

Calculation on this basis requires one new set 
of data in addition to those developed in the previous 
chapter: the series of total man-hours of productive 
labor actually performed each year* Since the same portion 
of the economy was covered, and the conceptual approach was 
the same, as in the preceding chapter, the relevant annual 
current-dollar series could be taken directly from the 
data of that chapter. These series are: variable capital, 
gross surplus-value, gross investment in fixed capital^ 
rate of capital consumption, and value of inventories o 



197 



Each of these must be transformed from a set of 
dollar magnitudes into the corresponding quantities of hours 
of socially necessary labor-time, in order to determine 
net surplu3-val\ie, capital consumption, and the total capital 
stocko The key problem, therefore, is to determine the 
ratio at which current dollars of a given year represent 
hoiirs of labor-time, the labor-content of the current dollar o 

Marx defined the labor-content of the price unit 
as the ratio between the number of hours of productive 
labor performed during the year, and the money-value of 
the net product of that year, the latter term being 
identically the mo ney net income of productive laborers 
and caoitalists,-^ 

An equivalent definition, which a3.1ows direct 
calculation in labor-units and is therefore preferable in 
the current context, is the ratio bet^^'een the labor-value 
of the gross income, the sum of current productive labor 
and capital consumption , and the money-value of the gross 
income, the sum of variable capital and gross surplus-value . 
It is this latter definition, therefore, that was used in 
this chapter to calculate the labor-content of the current 

dollar. 

Net surolus-value in labor-units is thus determined 



1, Cfo supra , cho I, p. 19, 



198 



by deducting from the number of hours of productive labor 
performed during a year the current-dollar total of variable 
capital multiplied by the labor-content of the current 

dollar. 

Of the four variables determining the labor- 
content of the current dollar, tvjo ( current-do llar variable 
capi tal and current-dollar gross surplus-value ) are 
directly known from the calculations of the previous chapter, 
and one ( current input of productive labor-time ) is 
directly established in this chapter. The fourth, labor- 
unit capital consumption , requires indirect computationo 

In any given year capital consumption consists Oj. 
t-wQ components: depreciation of the capital stock on 
hand at the beginning of the year and depreciation of fixed 
capital put in place during the year* Assuming that the 
initial labor-unit value of the stock of fixed capital Is 
knovn, it remains necessary to ascertain depreciation of 
the current year's gross investment in fixed capital o 

Simultaneous determination of these two variables 
is achieved through an iterative solutiona Ko matter to 
how many decimal places the quantities are calculated, for 
each level of precision there exists one and only one pair 
of values for capital consTjmption and labor-content of the 
current dollar consistent -with each other. From any starting 
point successive approximations mil finally yield these 



figures, 



199 



The remaining problem was determination of the 
labor-unit value of the stock of fixed capital at the start 
of I9OO0 Beginning x^ith the current-dollar value of fixed 
capital at the start of 1900, as established in the pre- 
vious chapter, it was possible through a similar iterative 
process to derive a figure for the labor-content of the 
1900 dollar which, multiplied by the original current- 
dollar capital stock, would yield an initial labor-value 
of fixed capital consistent with that labor-content of the 

1900 dollaro 

This figure, however, if unadjusted, would pro- 
nouncedly overstate the 1900 rate of profit and understate 
the 1900 organic composition of capitalo This is due to 
the fact, established in the previous chapter, that 
estimation of current-dollar fixed capital through a price- 
index with use-value denominator will understate the value 
of capital stock and of capital cons-amption relatively to 

estimauion tnrougn a price-j-m-iex ivxon xc. k^^x ^^x..^ 

tor if the productivity of labor is increasing over time. 

Since the initial underestimate of the labor- 
unit value of fixed capital would disappear progressively 
as the original capital stock was depreciated, the trend 
of the rate of profit would shoiNt a serious downward bias, 
and the trend of the organic cosiposition of capital would 
show an equally strong upward bias. 



1, Of. Supra , ch. VI, pp. 168-169. 



200 



Thus in order to remove this distortion and to 
make the original estimate of the labor-unit value of the 
capital stock methodologically homogeneous vith the sub- 
sequent estimates of the value of the capital stock it 
was necessary to correct for this understatement through 
a substantial increase in the original current-dollar 
estimate of the stock of fixed capital at the start of 1900. 

Calculation according to .the procedure outlined 
abwe yields theoretically correct estimates of the Marxian 
categories variable capital , surialus- value , and capital 
stock and of the fundamental Marxian ratios. The latter 
now include not only the organic compositi on of capital 
and the rates of profit and surplus-value , but also the 
net productivity of labor , expressed (given the appropriate 
price-index) as base-year dollars produced p er man-hour of 
productive labor . For every year labor net productivity is 
equal to the reciprocal of the product of the labor-content 
of the cvirrent dollar and the price index for that year» 



1, Or ganic composition of capital as computed is a true 
reflection of the Marxian ratio only if unemployment. 
Including short-time work, is at its minimum level. 
This minimum percentage mej vary over time (particularly 
if Marx was correct in his expectation that the "industrial 
reserve army" would tend to increase relatively to the 
employed labor force). But in every given business cycle 
it may be assumed to approximate the actual rate of 
unemployment during the prosperity phase. 



201 



There thus are three hypotheses to be tested: 

1. The Marxian rate of profit in the U. S. 
non-farm economy vill shoTj- a tendency to decline over 
the period 1900- i960. 

2. The organic composition of capital vill show 
a tendency to Increase over the same period. 

3. The net productivity of labor vill tend to 
increase more than -proportionally vith the organic 
composition of capital (i.e., in the equation '^= a Q^ 
u will prove to be greater than unity) » 

Invalidation of any of these hypotheses on the 
basis of data measured in labor-units would constitute 
empirical evidence contradicting the "Law of the Falling 
Tendency of the Rate of Profit" as formulated by Marx. 

Results 

The fundamental ratios and the labor-unit quanti- 

stocky as calculated for each year from 1900 to I96O 
according to the procedure just described, are set forth 
in Table VII- 1 and presented graphically (to semi- log 
scale) in Charts VII-1, VII-2, VII-3, and VII-4. Summary 
data on which Table VII- 1 is based are presented in 
Appendix C, 

Testing of the hypotheses set forth above yielded 
the following results: 



202 



lo The trend of the rate cf profit over the entire 
period was coTnputed on the basis of a regression with the rate 
of profit as the deoendentj and tiine as the independent, vari- 
able « All years in the period v/ere used, except for the years 
of deep depression (1931-1935) ^nd of the Second ¥orld War 

(19LLl-19i|5)c 

On a linear basis, this regression is 

p' = 11 08500 - ol277t (t counted from 1900) 
with correlation coefficient r = -0B79O 
On a logarithmic basis the regression is 

log p' = 2.51108 - 0OI619 
with correlation coefficient r ■= -.9065 
2« The drastic decline in the organic composition of 
canital during the Se-c:rr\d World War and the slow return of 
the organic composition to its pre-vjar level made it effec- 
tively impcssible to compute the trend of the organic composi- 
tion of capital through a regression covering the entire period. 
Instead, separate trends were computed for the pre-war and 

post-war periodso 

(a) For the pre-war period, the years used vjere the 
business-cycle peak years 1910, 1920, 1923, 1926, 1929, and 
1937 J the prosperous year 1905 (when productivity was at a 
relative peak) and the last real peacetime years, 1915 and 
19)4.0. The trend of the organic composition of capital was 
computed on the basis of a semi-logarithnic regression with 
the organic composition of capital as the dependent, and 
time as the independent, varlabloc 



203 



This regression is5 

log Q = laiW + c0075i+t (t counted from 1900) 
'With correlation coefficient r = o967 
(b) For the post-war period all years from 19)i-7 
through I960 except for the recession years 1914-9, 1951+, and 
1958 vjere usedo As for the pre-war period, the regression 
was comp-ated on a semi-logaritbi-aic basis <, 
This rftgression is: 

log Q = 1,09380 + o02382t (t counted from 19ii-7) 
mth correlation coefficient r = .982 
3. The relationship between the net productivity of 
labor (IT) and the organic composition of capital (Q) was com- 
outed through regressions with the logarithm of net productivi- 
ty (in I95I1 dollars per man hour) as the dependent, and the 
logarithm of the organic composition of capital as the inde- 
pendent, variables As in the computation of the trend of the 
organic composition of capital separate regressions viere com- 
puted for the pre-war and post-war periods, using the same 
years as were used for the trend of the organic composition of 

capitalo 

(a) For the pre-war period this regression was: 

log IT = I.805B7 log Q - 2oll056 
(T= .12118 q1. 80587) 
with correlation coefficient r = »888 

(b) For the post-war period this regression is: 

iog7r= 1.15331 log Q - .70135 

(T= .149583 qI-15331) 
with correlation coefficient r = o966 



204 



Chart VII -la Rate of Profit and Organic Composition 
of Capital (inverted), 1900-1960 
(Labor-Unit Basis) 



stmi-Locmiimic 1W» 'f*f 'to if'S Vt Hit 

2 Crclcs X 10 to th« loch 



rUO ItV IHII IfV 



ItSi 




W lUo 



205 



Chart VII -2. Rate of Profit and Rate of Sxirplus- 
Value, 1900-1960 (Labor-Unit Basis) 



P'-sJ 



3- 

Srml-Lofiarilhnilc 
;!C:>cI.-si 10 tolhclnch 




206 



CHART VU - 3 



ORQ&IilO C0HIOSITI09 OF CAPITAL - Selected Years , 1900-1960 




Chart VII-4* Labor Productivity and Organic 

Composition of Capital, Selected 
Years, 1900-1960 



207 



IT 



1905-1940 
(9 years) 



1947^1960 
(11 years) 







5 6 7 8 9 10 



208 



Table VII -1, 



Fundamental Ratios, 1900-1960 (Millions of 
Productive-Labor Manhours) 



Year 



1900 
1 

2 
3 

\ 

o 

7 
8 

9 
1910 
11 
12 
13 
11+ 
15 
16 

17 
18 

19 
1920 
21 
22 
23 

2i]- 

25 
26 

27 

28 

29 

1930 

31 
32 

33 
3k 
35 
36 
37 
38 
39 
19i|0 

^^ 
)+2 

^3 

i)4 

ii5 



(a) 

Variable 
Capital 



11^796. 6 

16270.5 
171if6,8 
1708lc8 
17330e9 
l8808o5 
20295.6 

20)|73a 

173980O 

201^13.9 
20053.0 

207 81 el 

228l8o7 

22096.4 
20573.0 
20386,11- 
23805«6 
2626l4.,3 
30157 cl 
27586.1 
27000.1 

20281.5 
23950,6 

27502.5 

251+66, [] 

25)|79.5 

25808.0 
27791.1 
25806,3 

26232. k 
23050 3 
21139.5 
20k6ii..5 
22177.3 
20153.2 
205^2.3 
22936.9 
2[}.836e5 
19529,1 
2l66ko2 

22867.3 
29211.1.3 
35980, ij. 
Ii.1360,2 
39338.9 
35119.2 



(b) 
Stir plus- 
Value 



9768. )| 

9687.5 
1096lo2 

12175o2 

lOll-llL.l 

iiii-90o5 

11557 ok 

12514.6,9 

12229.0 
11900.1 
13913.0 
13297.9 
121^95.3 
l3k3l}-o6 
128160O 
13011.6 

i)+k9k.ii- 
13783.7 

96kij..9 
92Lj.6.9 
11356.9 
9583o5 
858k.l4. 

10103.5 
9ki+2.6 

10867o5 
12086.0 

9793.9 
11689.7 
12311-8.6 

10301^,7 
6k61^.5 
1873.5 
1266.7 
1|M4.8 
5891+.7 
7569.1 
7720»5 
621l8o9 
6780,8 

7866.7 
9kl2.7 
10381.6 
11215.8 
11885.1 
10502.8 



(c) 

Capital 
Stock 



(d) 



9011^-3 06 
91269.6 
92898.3 
Q3865.O 

95090.7 
95870.0 
99830 ok 
103885.8 
10611+3.7 
107512.3 
1079kl^o2 

iio5ki=5 
112997.8 

lll|.662.3 
117131.5 
117289.7 
122136.1 

132[!.92oU 
111.1287. 3 
lk2757.3 
1L..0169.1[ 
138622.6 

139570,7 
lk0597.7 
1Il2815o2 

11.1.37080 k 
ll.k267.8 

Ik86k2c3 
lk6885.5 
ll+8ll].3ok 
ll|903k.2 
Ii4.7k09.1 
11x6957 o 5 
lk[i265o9 

133577 
130021 

129k69 

129595 

127792 

126lk3.6 

12571+7.7 

129933.5 

130766.9 

127000,8 

122080.1 

120352c 5 



66,02 

59.51+ 
63.93 
71.28 

6O0O9 
61.09 

56.95 
6lo28 

70.29 
58.29 
69.38 
63o99 
5)+. 76 
60,80 
62,30 
63.82 

60.89 
52^1.8 
31.98 

33.52 
1^2,06 
k7o25 
35.85 
36.7k 
37. 06 
k2.66 
1+6, 8Ii. 

35.25 
k5.30 
k7.07 
l+i+c71 
30,58 
9.15 
^.71 
22,05 
28068 
33o00 
3I0O9 
32,00 
31.30 

3i^.ko 
32.18 
28,86 
27.12 
30.12 
29,91 



(e) 

■2L 



(f) 

Q 



(g) 
TT 



10.81^ 
10.61 
lie 60 

12,97 

10,95 

11.99 

11,58 

12.08 

11.52 

llc07 

12.89 

12.03 

11.06 

11,72 

IO.9I1. 

11,09 

11»87 

10,i].l 

6.83 

6.1^.8 

8.11 

6,92 

6,15 

7.19 

6,61 

7.56 

8,38 

6.59 

7o96 

8,3k 
6.91 
k.39 
1,28 
.88 
3.33 

hA 

5c96 
i|,89 
5.38 
6.26 

7.25 
7.91^ 
8.83 
9o7k 
5.73 



3.67 
3.52 

3.31 
3.21 

3.k3 
3.16 

3.13 
3.15 
3. "^8 

3.33 
3.18 
3.21+ 
3.20 
3.23 
3.51 
3.51 
3.19 
3.31 
3-55 
3.87 
3o65 
i+o6k 
I+.29 
3.71+ 
1^,09 
3.95 
3.81 

3.95 
3.92 

3.8k 
k.k7 
5.3- 



6,5 

6,15 

5.43 

1^,92 
[^.2k 
3.98 
k.96 
l|.k3 
Il-,09 
3.36 
2.82 
2.k2 
2,38 
2 06k 



1.0372 
1.0137 
1.0169 
l,0k29 
1,0278 
I0O6I3 
1,0167 
.9967 
1.0579 

1.0593 
1,1126 

I0O685 
.985k 
1,1063 
I0O796 
1.1312 

I.i3ki 
i.oh.51 
.9809 
I06662 
1.1663 
i.25ki 
1,1679 

1.2555 
1,2862 

1,2909 
1.3512 
1,2702 
1.3950 
iai327 
loli3lk 
1.36I19 
1.1536 
1.0887 
1.I1I70 
1.^070 
1.571k 
1.6592 
lc7276 

1,7055 
1.8078 
1,7878 

1.7673 
1.726k 
1.7818 
1^7818 



209 



Year 



191+6 

kl 
1+8 

^9 
1950 

51 
52 

53 

56 

57 

58 

59 

I960 



(a) 

Variable 
Capital 



35167 o8 
36906,8 
3t^329o8 
32020,6 
3)4467 « 6 
36953.2 
37505.6 
39202. i|. 

35537.5 
35755.5 
37136.5 
36300,6 

33501.5 
3ii-793.3 
3i)-590 = 3 



(b) 
Surplus- 
Value 



8397o2 

8II1.7.2 

107il.8o2 

8851 oi| 

8i^.9I^.i+ 
9157.8 
8712,11. 

8169.6 
7703.5 
960U.5 
8962.5 
8i^.95oi4 
7553.5 
8712o7 
81+53.7 



(c) 

Capital 
Stock 



(d) 



126966.1 
1370980! 
11+0986. It 
Iil.k680o6 
Ii.8l08o2 

15I}.679.3 
1'59670.8 

162697*7 
161^056.8 

I65li|.8c7 
171557.9 
176559ol 
178211.606 
17850606 
180851. []. 



(e) 



(f) 

Q 



(g) 
I 



23,88 
22.08 
31o31 
27«65 
2[|..65 
2i!..78 
23o23 
20 08k 
21.68 
26.86 
2ti.ll+ 
23.1^0 

22,55 
25. 01^ 

2[j.al|l+ 



6.62 


2,91 


5.9i+ 


3.01+ 


7o62 


3.13 


6.12 


3.5I}- 


5.71+ 


3cl^5 


5.92 


3.35 


5.146 


3.45 


5.02 


3.I1-3 


I+.70 


3.79 


■^.82 


3.6k 


5.22 


3.72 


il..8l 


3o9i+ 




it-=3k 


l+.io 


i|..68 


i}..20 



7121 
7110 
9232 

9l|J+6 
2o0017 
2,0236 

2,0531+ 
2,09l|-2 

2.1713 
2.3382 

2.3503 
2.39ii.2 

2,1+071+ 
2.1+993 
2,5591 



Soi:irces: 

Column a (Variable Capital): Table VI-1, column a 
multiplied by Table C-II, column £. 

Column b (Surplus-Value) : Table C-I, column £ less 
column a of this table. 

Column £ (Capital Stock): Table C-II, column £. 

Column d [s' (rate of surplus-value)]: Column b 
divided by coliimJi a. 

Column s_ [p' (rate of profit)]: Column b divided 
by column £, 

Column f [Q (organic composition of capital)]: 
Colxomn c of this table divided by Table C-I^ colvimn £c 

Column £ [^[(net productivity of labor)]: Table C-II, 
column f divided by Table C-II, column £, 



..^ 



210 



Sources and Methods 

In addition to the series taken directly from 
Chapter V, the statistical sources used in this chapter 
were: John W. Kendrick, Productivity Trends in the U. 3» t 
U, S« Bureau of the Census, Census of Manufactures - 1958 
and Census of Mineral Industries - 1958 ; and the U. S« 
Bureau of Labor Statistics, Bulletin 1312. Employment and 
Earnings o 

A, Manhours of Productive Labor (Appendix C, Table I) 

The basic series of employee manhours worked 
annually per industrial Idivision was obtained from un- 
published worksheets of the National Bureau of Economic 
Research underlying the annual manhour estimates published 
in Product Jyity Trends in the U» S. 

The percentage of this working time constituting 
productive labor was determined in the same way as wages 
for productive labor were estimated in the previous chapter: 

lo Manufacturing » Manhours worked were allocated 
between productive and unproductive labor on the basis of 
the ratio of production workers to all employees given by the 
1958 Census of Manufactures (I, 1-3) for the years 1899, 
190^^-, 1909, 191^, 1919, 1921, 1923, 1925, 1927, 1929, 1933, 
1935* 1937* 1939j 19^7, and annually from 19^9 to 195S. For 
other years between 1919 and i960 the ratio of productive 
laborers to all employees was estimated by Interpolation on 



21] 



the basis of the ratio of "production workers" to "all employ- 
ees" as given in Employment and Earnings , For ..the period 
I9OO-I919 it x-7as estimated by linear Interpolation between 
the benchmark figures given by the Census o 

2e Transportation? Gonmiuni cations and Public 
Utilities; Services; and A.gri cultural Ser-^'-ices, Forestry, 
and Fisheries , ?'he allocation of manhours derived for 
manufacturing was used to estimate manho^^rs of productive 
labor worked in these industry groups^ 

3o Mining o The ratio of "production workers" to 
"all employees" given by the 1958 Census of Mineral Industries 
(I, 1-k) for the ye«rs 1902, 1909, 1919, 1929, 1939, 195i+> 
and 1958 was taken as the basis for allocation of manhours 
betvjeen productive and unproductive laboro For other yeara 
between 19ij.7 and I960 this ratio was estimated by inter- 
polation on the basis of the ratio of "production workers" 
to "all employees" given in Employment and Earnings , and 
between 1900 and 19i|-6 by interpolation on the basis of the 
percentages previously determined for manufacturing. 

I4.0 Constructiono For 19il-7-1960 the ratio used 
to allocate manhours was taken from the ratio of "construc- 
tion v/orkers" to "all employees" given by Employment and 
Earnings . This series was extrapolated back to 1900 on 
the basis of the percentages previously determined for 
manufacturing o 



212 



B, Capital Stock, Capital Consumption, and the Labor-Content 
of the Current Dollar (Appendix C, Table II) 

lo Depreciation Rate e The average depreciation 
rate established in the previous chapter for each year 
(defined as current-dollar capital consumption for the year 
divided by the mid-year value of the stock of fixed capital) 
was used as the depreciation rate for the same year in this 
chapter, since the division of cijrrent gross investment into 
groups of differing average life-expectancy, on which the 
whole computation of stock and consumption of fixed capital 
is based, is not changed by any change in the unit of 
measurement (and the consequent implicit price-index) used© 

2o Initial Determination of the Labor-Content of 
the 1900 Dollar » The current-dollar valuation of aggregate 
fixed capital at the beginning of 1900 was taken from the 
data of the preceding chapter as a starting point. This 
value was expressed in units of one itiillion hours of 
socially necessary labor-time by the following methodtl 

(a) The initial approximate labor-content of the 
1900 dollar was determined by dividiing manhours of productive 
labor worked during 1900 by the sum of current-dollar 
variable capital and net sxir plus -value. 

(b) The current-dollar value of fixed capital at 



1, This computation is presented in detail in Exhibit A 
appended to this chapter. 



213 



the start, of 1900 -.as converted into labor units through 
multiplying it by the first approximation to the labor- 
content of the 1900 dollaro 

(c) Depreciation on the initial caoital stock 
m labor units was calculated through laultiplication by 
that year's depreciation rateo 

(d) The second approximation to the labor-content 
of the 1900 dollar .;as deterroined through dividing the sum 
of man-hours worked, initial capital consumed, and estimated 
new capital consumed by the s^-^m of c^ox- rent-dollar variable 
capital and^ross surplus-value (i.e., capitalist-sector 

gross income)© 

(e) App.roxlmate labor-unit current investment was 
detemined through multiplying 1900 current-dollar gross 
investment by the second approximation to the labor-content 

of the 1900 dollaro 

(f ) Approximate depreciation on current investment 
vas calculated through multiplying l/2 the figure established 
in step (e) by the year's depreciation rate, 

(g) The third approximation to the labor-content 
of the 1900 dollar was determined to six decimal places 
through dividing the sum of manhours worked, initial capital 
consumed, and new capital consumed (per step f) by current- 

dollar gross income « 

(h) The initial labor-unit value of fixed capital 

.,4-on nr, ^hP basis of the estimated labor-content 
■was recomputea on one od^axa uj 



214 



of the 1900 dollar established by step (g)o 

(1) Steps (c) through (h) were repeated until 
the fig\:^e established hj step (g) was repeatedo 

The labor-unit value of fixed-capital at the end 
of 1900 was determined as the algebraic sum of initial 
value of fixed capita.l, current gross investment, original 
capital consujtied, and new capital consumedo 

•3., Annual determination of the labor- content of 
the current dollar p For each year the initial labor-unit 
value of fixed capital is identically the value of fixed 
capital at the end of the previous yearo VFitb this as a 
starting point, the program for computing the labor-content 
of the current dollar consists of steps (c) through (g) 
described above, reiterating steps (e) through (g) until 
the figure established in (f) is repeatedo 

I4.0 Correction of Bias , Fixed capital in labor- 
units and the labor-content of the current dollar were 
calculated through 1929. The mid-year fixed capital 
estimates for 1925 through 1929 were then reconverted into 
"current dollars" through multiplication hj the labor- 
content estimate for each year. These estimates were then 
compared to the current-dollar estimates of the stock of 
fixed capital derived in the previous chapters 

It was revealed by this comparison that the 1925- 
1929 c-iprent-dollar estimates based on a labor-value index 
were approximately l^fo above those based on a use-value 



'V I ^ 216 



index, although the two totals for 1900 were identical » 
Fifteen per cent wae therefore taken ae an indicator of the 
approximate "bias in the 1900 current-dollar estimate of 

xxji.Su. uapxbaXo 

Accordingly, the final calculation of all quantities 
in labor-units was carried out according to the procedure 
described above, but using as a starting point the previous 
estimate of current-dollar fixed capital at the start of 
1900 multiplied by 1.15 o 

C, Computation of Basic Categories an d Batios 

1« Capital Stock o The capital stock for each year 
was calculated through multiplying the current-dollar 
value of inventories by the labor-content of the current 
dollar for that year, and adding this quantity to the mid- 
year value of the stock of fixed capital, 

2. Variable Capital , Variable Capital for each 
year was determined through multiplying current-dollar net 
income of productive laborers by the labor-content of the 
current dollar for that year. 

3. Surplus-Value . Surplus-value for each year 
was determined by subtracting labor-unit variable capital 
from total manhours of productive labor worked in that year. 

k,^ Net Productivity of Labor . The net productiv- 
ity of labor for each year wae determined through dividing 
the reciprocal of the price-index used in the previous 



216 



chapter by the labor-content of the current dollar for that 
vear. Since 195)+ is the base year of the index, net produc- 
tivity of labor for every year is conputed In 1951+ dollars 
per manhour o 

Evaliia.tion of Data 

Since the data used in this chapter are basically 
the same as those used in the previous chapter, the 
considerations regarding reliability and interpretation of 
the data expressed in that chapter (pp. 192-4) apply fully 
to the present chapter. 

The pattern of results emerging from the current- 
dollar calculation is confirmed by computation in units 
of socially necessary labor-time. As expected, the basic 
trends x-ere shown more strongly than in the previous chapter 
- the rate of profit tended to decline by lo62^ per year, 
as against a rate of decline of 1,09$^ in the previous 
calculation; and the organic composition of capital increased 
by 31?^ from 1903 to I960, as against pid Increase over the 
sarfie span of 22% shox%m previously o 

These results tend strongly to confirm all the 
hvDotheses testedo 

It should be noted that the tendency of the Marxian 
rate of profit to decline, as is to be observed from 
Chart VII-1, cannot be viewed as a smooth and sustained 



217 



process. Within each of two sub-periods, the pre-V/orld- 
War I years 1900-1915 and the decade 1920-1929, no 
significant over-all fall in this rate took place (apart 
from cyclical fluctuations,) though the average rate in 
1920-1929 was substantially lower than that of 1900-1915; 
and the Great Depression and Second World War resulted in 
a recovery of the Marxian rate of profit to well above its 
1929 peak. Only within the post-World War II sub -period 
(1946-1960) is a sustained falling tendency to be observed, 
This pattern cannot entirely be ascribed to the "counter- 
acting" factors which, Marx contended, made the fall in 
the rate of profit a gradual tendency whose net effect 
should be clear only over the long r\in. To a very 
significant extent the stepwise fall reflects the demar- 
cation between periods of different burdens of taxation 
on the U.S. economy. This factor will be discussed in the 
following chapter. 



218 



Exhibit VII-A ; initial DeterminaUon of the Labor-Content 

of the 1900 Dollar 

Ao Information from basic series: 

(1) Depreciation rate « .0592j67 

(2) Total Productive Labor 21}., ^65 

(mi 11 ions of manhours) 

(3) Current Dollar Cross Income .......... o.L|./'U 

(millions of dollars) 

{[].) Current Dollar Gross Investment o 1|>551 

(millions of dollars) 

B« Suoplementsry Data: 

(5) Current-Dollar Value of Fixed Capital l8,l69.tl. 
at start of 1900 (millions of dollars) 

'6) Revised Initial Value of Fixed Capital 20,89l+o8 
(16,169.1-:- X lol5) 

(7) Current Dollar Net Income (from 7,383 

Chapter VI, Table Vl-I) (millions of 
dollars) 

(8) First Estimate of Labor-Content of 3,3272 

1900 Dollar [ (2) ^ (7)1 

(9) First Estimate of Labor-Value of Fixed 69,521o2 " 

Capital, start of 1900 [(6) x (8)] 

Co Computation: 

Iteration h c d _e_ _f_ _£_ 

1 69.^21.2 1j,121c7 3oIl06328 5,283.2 lg6«6 3.|4-0^3^8 

2 71 a 1 a 218 5 3.1^16777 ^ 299.li- 157.1 3.14-16836 
3! 71 39^1 S 232 7 3.bl8<12 5 302.1 lg7.2 3ol|l8<2l+ 
i 71 k29 [| k 2311.8 3aLl8772 5,302.< 1^7.2 3.1i.l8772 
^' 71 k3)I 6 k>35oi 3.ill8808 ^302,6 1^7.2 3.1^8808 

t: n:w^ t^Mr?. iXi^m 5,302,6 157.?. 3.i,.i88i9 

7. 7i;i!.3i5 K235.2 3.kl88l9 5,302.6 157.2 3oiilS8l9 

Year-end value of Fixed Capital - 72,3^5»7 

(Explanation of computation procedure given in section III - 
B - 2 of this chapter.) 



219 



Exhibit VII-B ; Calculation of the L abor-Content of the 

1901 Dollar 

A, Basic Data: 

(1) Deoreciatlon rate 0591^17 

(2) Total Productive Labor 2^,958 

(3) Current-Dollar Gross Income o 8:.675 

(ll) Current-Dollar Gross Investment ... 1,606 

{^) Value of Fixed Capital at end of ^o oi t^ -7 

1900 o I^,3i\-t>*( 

B, Computation: 

(ci) (5) X (1) )i,279.1j 

(dx) [(2) + (c) + (c/25)l i (3) 3.^.263 

(ex) (iJ-) ^ (^) 5,502.6 

(fx) l/2(e) X (1) 162.7 

(Sl) 1(2) -^ (c) + (f)] 1 (3) 3.1^25363 

(02) 0-1-) X (s) 5,501.1 

(fg) 1/2(62) X (1) 162,7 

Year-end vslue of fixed capital - 73,iiO!4..7 
(5) - (c) + (§2) - ^-2) 

(Explanation of computation procedure is given in section 
III - B - 3 of this chapter,) 



/^^■■ 



220 



Chapter viii 
conclusions 

The Confronta t ion of Marx'e Predictions with the Faots 

This study has made it clear that the U. So rate 
of profit as defined "by Marx, v;hether calculated on a 
labor-unit or current-dollar haeis^ has fallen drastically 
over the past sixty years e The organic composition of 
capital has simultaneously increased, though not in as 
pronoimced a wayo The facts of the modern U« So economy 
thus tend to confirm, at least in general outline, the 
*<lav/" that Marx regarded as basic to his general theory 
of capitalist development* 

At the same time, however, this study has 
revealed another major tendency which Marx definitely 
did not predict and x-Jhich contradicts his anticipations; 
the decline of the rate of surplus-value from a range of 
35-50^ in the 1920 *s (and of 55«70^ in the pre«World War 
I period) to a range of 20-2?^ in the last decade* 

Marx, of course, excluded a decline in the rate 

of Burplus-value as an explanation of a falling rate of 

profit! 

The falling tendency of the rate of 
profit is accompanied by a rising 
tendency of the rate of surplus-value, 
i.e., in the degree of exploitation of 



/'N 



221 



labor. Nothing is more absurd, there- 
fore, than to account for a fall, in the 
rate of profit by a rise in the wage- 
rate, although exceptionally this may 
also be the case*l 

The rate of profit sinks not bec-ause 
the laborer is less exploited but be- 
cause less labor is employed in pro- 
portion to the employed capital in 
general e^ 

How drastically this tendency contradicts l-iarx^s 
explicit prediction is shown by the fact that the 
quantity (the "mass") of surplus-value fell by alraogt 
a third between 1929 and i960, from 12,3^9 to 8,i^5^ 
labor-units (the i960 total, in fact, was less than the 
total for any year before 193lS)o Yet Marx repeatedly, 
and most forcefully, insists on the "law that a fall in 
the 2?ate of profit due to the development of productive- 
ness is accompanied by an increase in the mass of pro- 
fit"!^ 

As the process of production and accu- 
mulation advances therefore, the mass 
of available and appropriated surplus- 
labor, and hence the absolute mass of 
profit appropriated by the social capi- 
tal, must groWo Along with the volume, 
however, the same laws of production 
and accumulation increase also the value 
of the constant capital in a mounting 
progression more rapidly than that of 
the variable part of capital, invested 



le Capital , III, 281, 
2o Ibid . , po 288, 
3o Ibid . , p. Z6l^, 



222 



as it is in living lafcor*. Hence, the 
same laws produce for the social capi- 
tal a growing absolute mass of profit? 
and a falling rate of profit o^ 

The question is therefore posedt to what extent 

does the observed fall in the rate of profit reflect the 

cause posited by Mars (iees, the increasing organic 

composition of capital) as against the explanation Marx 

excluded? 

A quantitative answer can be indicated on the 
basis of the data* Comparing the level of the key 
variables (labor-unit basis) in 1905 to their level in 
i960 J we see that the rats of profit decreased from 
11b 99^ to ^o68^s an annual rate of -1<.72^'; the organic 
composition of capital increased from 3«l6 to i!'o20, an 
anniial rate of 0«52^ (for its reciprocal, a rate of 
-0.52^); ^nd the rate of surplus-value decreased froni 
6lo09fa to 2^0^^%, so that the percentage of the working- 
day forming surplus-value ( -^ ■ ^." -' i ) decreased at an 
annual rate of -1.20^« Thus 30^ of the observed fall 
in the rate of profit between these dates is accounted 
for by the increase in the organic composition of capital, 
and ^Q% is accounted for by the decrease in the rate of 
surplus-value » 

A falling tendency of the rate of surplus-value 



1« Capital « III, 256. 



22'3 



implies a tendency of hourly real vages to rise more 
rapidly than the net productivity of labor, (i.e., in 
terms of the model in Chapter V, b, the elasticity of 
the real wage vith respect to labor -productivity, has a 
value greater than unity.) From the data shown in 
Appendix D, Table II, it will be seen that Lhls elasti- 
city has kept a fairly uniform level throughout the 
period: real wages have tended to increase about 1.3 
times as fast as labor net productivity. 

It is in this connection that the "unproductive 
expenditures," with which Gillman mistakenly attempted 
to rescue Marx, have real significance. It is obvious 
that the "necessary but unproductive costs'*- of main- 
taining the commercial and governmental apparatus have 
increased vastly during this century, not only absolutely 
but also relatively to the total national product. 
These expenses, like the necessary allowance for consump- 
tion of fixed capital, must be deducted from the total 
goods and services produced by the capitalist sector in 
order to determine the net pro duct available for con- 
sumption and investment by the capitalists and workers. 

It follows that, since an increasing relative 
amount of a worker's direct physical product constitutes 
constant capital, his net productivi ty grows less rapidly 



1. Capital, II, 151. 



224 



than his gross productivity * This is clearly shown by the 
indexes of gross and net labor productivity given in 
Appendix D- Table T* The index of real wages, which in- 
creases faster than the index of net productivity, grows 
(after 1929) more slowly than the index of gross productiv- 
ity« The lag of net productivity behind gross productivity 
thus more than accounts! for the actual observed decline in 
the rate of surplus-valae<» 

The existence of such a lag, indeed ^ is required 
by Marx's model of capitalist development o Marx explicitly 
predicts that the organic composition of capital will tend 
to increase, and that the rate of turnover of the stock of 
capital (i.e,, the efficiency with which this stock is 
utilized) will also tend to increase. It follows that the 
relative share of the value of the gross product consisting 
of constant capital must tend over time to increase a 

Questions necessarily arise, however, if this 
argument is applied not only to the expansion of distri- 
butional and administrative overhead costs required by 
the increasing sophistication and complexity of the pro- 
ductive apparatus, but also to the weight of taxation. 
The increase in the tax biirden during the past half -century 
has been largely, though not entirely, caused by the 
increase in direct and indirect military expenditures. 
Such expenditures, of co\irse, have political causes, and 
cannot be treated as simple reflections of changes within 



225 



the capitalist economic system. •'• 

To what extent do these "politically determined" 
costs account for the actual decline in the rates of 
surplus-value and profit? If not for them, might not the 
rate of surplus -value even have increased enough to 
counteract the increased organic composition of capital and 
thereby totally to prevent a fall in the rate of profit? 

In order to reply to these questions it was 
necessary to isolate the effect of national, state, and 
loca:l taxes upon the rate of surplus -value, and thereby 
upon the rate of profit. This was done for every year by 
expanding the net totals of variable capital and (labor- 
unit depreciation) surplus-value by the amounts previously 
deducted as direct personal and corporate taxes. The ratio 
between these two aggregates gave a new "expanded rate of 
surplus-value gross of taxes" which could then be applied 
to the total manhours of productive labor and organic 
composition of capital established in Chapter VII to produce 
an "expanded total sxorplus -value gross of taxes" and an 
"expanded rate of profit gross of taxes" for each yearo 
The degree of expansion indicates the effect of changes in 
the structure and rates of taxation upon the amount and 
rate of profit. 



1. In the strict Marxian sense, it is true, they ultimately 
do reflect changes in the economic base. Marxists have con- 
tended that in the last analysis «ars among capitaj.xsu 
states are fought for basically economic objectives, and 
that this is particularly so in the "epoch of imperialism. 



226 



The resxilts of this computation (presented in 
Appendix D, Table IV and Charts I and II) can be s\aimned up 
in a single pair of figures: in 1905 the "expanded rate of 
profit gross of taxes" was 12,88^ (11.99?& on the previous 
basis,) and in 1960 the "expanded rate of profit gross of 
taxes" was 7.95% (4.88?^ on the previous basis.) Thus over 
this span the "expanded rate of profit gross of taxes" fell 
at an annual rate of .88^ , as against an annual rate of 
decrease of 1.72^ for the observed Marxian rate of profit. 
Comparison of the two figures shows that the increasing tax 
burden is sufficient explanation for an annual rate of 
decrease of .84^ in the rate of profit, or nearly 50^ of 
the observed rate of decrease, ^ 

The effect of taxation is therefore far from a 
full explanation for the fall in the rate of profit » It is, 
ho^vever, a vary substantial partial explanation for the 
fall in the rate of svirplus -value, which, we have seen, 
accounts for 70^ of the observed decline in the Marxian 

profit-rate. 

Marx's explanation of the falling tendency of 
the rate of profit as a result of a rising organic com- 



1, A inaxin»:;in estimate of this effect is gxven by comparxson 
of the regression coefficient for the "expanded rate of 
profit gross of taxes", -.00619, to the regression 
coefficient for the observed profit-rate derived m Chapter 
VII -.01619. This would indicate that increased taxation 
r^an' account for almost 62^ of the observed rate of decline. 



227 



position of capital thus appears, on the basis of the 
data for the entire period, to be at least partially 
adequate: even apart from the unforeseen decrease in 
the rate of surplus -value, the rate of profit would still 
have fallen significantly over the period, and for the 
reason Marx specified. 

2. . The Phas es, of 20t h-Gentury U,S. Economic Development 

The problem of explaining the falling rate of 
profit appears in a somevhat different light if the 
general trend of development is analyzed in terms of a 
division into separate periods. 

It is clear at first glance that, in terms of 
the variables relevant to this study, the 20th-century 
U.S. economy has gone through at least three distinct 
periods: the pre- 1929 era; the great depression and 
second ¥orld >rar; and the post-var period. 

It can be contended that the years 1930-19^5 
constitute a qualitative break in American history: that 
the society emerging from the second World ¥ar was psy- 
chologically, sociologically, and economically of a dif- 
ferent sort from the one that crashed in 1929. I myself 



1. A case can be made out for treating the pre-Vorld Var I 
years as a separate period. However justified this may be, 
it is not best to do so in the present context, partially 
for considerations of the precision of the data (cf . supra 
ch, VI, p. 192) but mainly since the division would not 
reflect a drastic break in the same sense as the others 
do . 



228 



would accept this view only with grave reservations (it 
is, for instance, obviously false in regard to the U.S. 
Congress and dubious at best in regard to the stock 
market and the American League). In terms of Marxian 
economics, however, the years of depression and war 
brought truly decisive changes at basic points. 

(a) In the -most spectacular sense the years 
1930-1945 were marked by " slaughtering of the values of 
capitals ." Between 1930 and 1945 the capital stock fell 
from 149 billion to 120 billion labor units, a net dis- 
investment of some 20% (in only one other year of the 
entire period, 1921, was there any disinvestment at all) . 
At the same time this was a period of rapid technological 
and scientific advance, so that in 19^5 much of the re- 
maining capital stock was already obsolescent. 

(b) The depression and. war years saw the forma- 
tion and consolidation of mass industrial unions in the 
basic sectors of American industry, with a corresponding 
change in the institutional structure of the labor market. 
At the same time the government budget and tax system 
emerged as a major economic fact (i.e., as a major factor 
restraining the growth of net labor -productivity) . 

In comparison to 1929> the situation in 1946 (so 
far as our statistics are concerned) was marked by two 
major changes: 

- the rate of sxirplus- value had fallen by virtu- 



229 



ally 50^ (from 47^ to 2h%) 

- the organic composition of capital as computed 
had fallen by ahout 25% (from 3.84 to 2.91). 

If the post- 1945 period is judged on its ovn, 
certain sharp differences from the pre-¥ar epoch become 
apparent. In the first place, after 1946 the falling 
tendency of the rate of surplus -value is completely 
arrested: fluctuations continue vithin a relatively 
narrow range, hut without discernible trend. (The fact 
that this stability has been accompanied by steadily 
growing unemployment, however, indicates that in a full- 
employment situation the balance might well swing to the 
side of labor.) 

Secondly, technological progress has been ex- 
tremely capital-intensive, as indicated by the value of 
1.153 (as against I.8II in the pre-war period) obtained 
for u in the equation ffs aQ""^ (Cf . ch. VII, p.203) . Con- 
sequently the organic composition of capital increased 
from 1946 to i960 by 45^ (from 2.91 to 4.20). 

The result has been an over -a 11 fall in the rate 
of profit at a pace much faster than the trend for the 
whole 1900-1960 period. This is, in fact, virtually an 
"ultra-Marxian" picture - a situation in which the or- 
ganic composition of capital is rising rapidly and in 
which the "counteracting causes" are mainly inoperative. 

There can at this point be no conclusive answer 



230 



to the question whether this picture will continue to 
apply even for the next decade: not only because 15 
years is too short a period to support a firm prediction, 
but also because there is no assurance that this is in- 
deed a "normal" period in its ovn right, and not merely 
a phase of recovery to some much longer-term trend. 

If, however, we accept tentatively the hypothesis 
that the post-war parameters will continue to apply in 
the next decade, it is difficult to escape the stag- 
nationist implications of the Marxian theory, since a 
1.% annual growth rate of the capital stock (the 1953- 
1960 average) permits less than a 2% growth rate of net 
product when u = 1.153. Whether or not this proves to 
be the case depends to a large degree on political and 
social factors that we cannot go into here. In the purely 
economic sense, however (i.e., abstracting from changes in 
the institutional context), the Marxian model leaves vir- 
tually no room for a real acceleration in the growth rate. 

•^. Bearing on the Marxian System 

What, then, is the bearing of this study upon the 
Marxian theoretical struct^ire as a whole? 

It is plain, despite the scope, power, and basic 
clarity of his thought, that jMarx left his system of 
economic analysis in a crude and unfinished form, that 
many vital concepts were poorly defined, and that essential 
parts of his model were not developed beyond the stage of 



231 



artificial and unrealistic schemata. The endeavor to 
make an empirical test of one of the major "laws" of this 
model, therefore, required the clarification and refor- 
mulation of these aspects of Marx's doctrine. 

If this "book has made a theoretical contribution, 
it has not done so through development of any new theories 
on a Marxian basis, or through a new critique of Marx. 
V/hat has been accomplished has been: 

(1) To state or restate the basic categories of 
Marx's system in a ^ay which establishes both their co- 
herence with each other and their identifiability to em- 
pirically knowable economic magnitudes. 

(2) To validate the "law of the falling tendency 
of the rate of profit" both as a vital part of I-Iarx's 
model of economic development under capitalism and as a 
logically correct and necessary deduction from the basic 
premises of the Marxian system, 

^5^ To demons trate practically that the Marxian 
model can be tested by the facts of the U.S. economy = 

The data developed through this test, as pre- 
sented in the previous chapters and in this conclusion, 
speak for themselves. They show clearly that Marx was no 
infallible prophet, that certain of his predictions proved 
to be invalid. But they also confirm that Marx was 
correct on the issues he regarded as decisive: the 
rising tendency of the organic composition of capital 



232 



^ 



and the falling tendency of the rate of profit. 

Confirmation on this vital score is not in any 
sense "confirmation" of the Marxian economic theory as 
a whole - something which is in any case conceivable 
only through the integration of vast amounts of post- 
Marxian theory into the Marxian structure. ¥ha.t this 
study has shown is not that Marx is "right" or "wrong" 
the point is, that he is relevant . 



233 



APPENDIX A 

ANAL!fSIS OF THE BORTKIEWICZ-SVffiEZY CRITICISM 
OF MARX'S SOIUTION TO THE "TRANSFORMATION PROBLEM" 



234 



APPENDIX A 

This solution to the "transfomation problem" was 
of considerable theoretical importance to Marx because it 
inalntained the equality of value and price in aggregate 
terms x^hile showing that prices of production are ultimately 
dependent upon values and must change in a determinate way 
with changes in value (|| = ^)* It has, however, been 
criticized as being inconsistent with other essential 
aspects of the Marxian sjrstemo 

This criticism was developed by Bortkiewicz^ together 
with an alternative solution, and both his criticism and 
"solution" were presented and endorsed by Sweezy in "The 
Theory of Capitalist Deveiopmento" 

The criticism, as Sweezy states it, is iiiat "ths 
Marxian itb thod of transformation results in a violation of 
tte equLlibriuin of simple reproduction, "2 The Marxian model 
of "simple reproduction", of coiorse, requires that in an 
economy divided into two "Departments," Dept, I producing 
means of production and Dept. II means of cons^jm^ption, the 
constant capital consumed in Dept. II be exactly replaced 



1 "On the Correction of y.arz's Fundamental Theoretical 
Construction in the Third Volume of Capital ," reprinted as 
an appendix to Hilferding, opo cit, 

2o Sweezy, opo clt« , pe lli^« 



235 



by the new product (variable capital plus surplus-value) 
in Dept, I so that the total capital stock neither in- 
creases nor decreases: Cp =v-+s^« If^ however, the 
organic composition of capital is different in the two 
lines, then _s is unequal to £^, and consequently v^ + p, 
will be unequal to £p © Marx's error, according to Sweezy, 
stems from the fact that 

In his price scheme the capitalists' 
outlays on constant and variable capital 
are left exactly as they were in the value 
scheme: in other words, the constant 
capital and the variable capital used in 
production are still expressed in value 
term So Outputs, on the other hand, are 
expressed in price terms, 1 

If this criticism is valid it has grave implica- 
tions: both the uniform rate of profit and the relation- 
ship of siraple reproduction are necessary features of the 
basic Marxian macro-economic equilibrium model, and if 
the two are contradictory the systai as a whole fails to 
meet the elementary test of internal consistencyo More- 
over, if the contradiction can be resolved only by allowing 
the sum of prices of production to diverge from the sum 
of values this would negate the essential meaning of the 
Marxian "law of value" itself, knocking the central prop 



1« Sweezy, op. cito , p. Il5< 



236 



out frorn under the entire structure.^ 



in one sense the Sweezy-Bortkie.Ticz criticism can 
be ansv^ered quite simply. Marx expressed the relation- 
ship bet..een value and price of production as a function 
of the relationship bet.;een the organic composition of 



1 -ince it co-cludes with a sum of prices unequal to the 
sint? vaiues;"the Sweezy-Eor tkie.icz "f l-\f°f //.^'^ 
^T^fnrt no sol^^tion but rather the proclamation of the 
i?sence 0° any so?Stion to the problem with which Marx was 
concprnedl Without entering upon a detailed analysis of the 
Bo?tkIewicz-Sweezy method, it should be noted that, though 
nre tending to generality, it applies only under the 
SDOSsibll condition of the absence of fixed capital and 
equal periods of tur-nover for the variable and constant 
portions of the circulating capital. Moreover its entire 
approach, which separates out a third Department producing 
oSlT "luiury goods^ which then are treated as the numeraire 
for the vhole system (on the ground that gold is produced 
in this department) is quite invalid and leads to the 
conclusion, ridiculous in Marxist terms but which Sweezy 
actually considers an important insight, that 'the^rate of 
profit depends only upon the conditions of production 
existing in those industries which contribute direcly or 
indirectly to the m^ke-up of reel wages. Conditions 
existing in industries catering solely to capitalists con- 
sumption are relevant only in so far as they influence 
conditions in the wage-goods industry (p. l^M-Jo 

In any case gold, as it comes from the refiner, is never 
anv sort of "luxury good": it is partly raw material, 
constan t capital , to be used in the production of luxury 
goods " "workers consumer goods" and indus-crial materials 
of maiy sortsj the rest constitutes means of circulation. 
In this latter capacity it can be treated as a "department 
of production" in itself, as Marx suggests in Volume II 
(though the moment the domestic monetary unit is made incon- 
vertible the production of gold becomes merely one line of 
industry among many) bat at the level of abstraction involved 
in the discission of prices of production the numeraire is 
simply irrelevant: all that is necessary is that prices and 
values be calculated in the same units , which is precisely 
what Bortkiewicz and Sweesy do not do, . ^ n 4.^,, 

These are secondary objections. The fundamental thing 
wT'one with the Sweezy-Bortkiewicz m.ethod, as we will^see in _ 
the following pages, is tha.t it fails to understand the Marxian 
category value as it is concretised in relation to price of 
productiono 



237 



capital characteristic of each specific industry, and the 
organic composition of the social capital as a whole. 
Svjeezy and Bortkie-wicz, on the other hand, pose the 
problem in terms, not of specific industries, hut of 
entire "Departments of Production." 

But, although Marx at one point ^ does use an 
arithmetic illustration involving a higher organic composi- 
tion in Department I, what reason is there to expect the 
organic composition of capital to be different in the two 
departments? Differences among industries rest on the 
specific technical characteristics of each industry, in 
a modern economy em.bracing hundreds or thousands of 
distinguishable "industrieso" On what is based the 
supposed difference between the two departments of produc- 
tion, each of which is an enormously aggregative entity? 

Most industries, it must be remembered, belong 
simultaneously to both . departments, since their classifica- 
tion is not alorig technical lines but by whether they sell 
to individual final consumers or to intermediary enterprises 
Accordingly, to assert the existence of a characteristic 
difference between the organic compositions in Departments 
I and II involves the implicit assumption of a substantial 
correlation, positive or negative, between organic 
composition of capital in an industry and the percentage 



le Capital, II, 5,96 < 



258 



of its output sold to individual final consumers a 

The existence in reality of such a correlation is 
most improbable, since it is evident that even among 
industries entirely within Department I there are to be 
found whole groups with relatively labor-intensive technol- 
ogy (machine-tool production, for instance,) alongside 
extremely capital-intensive sections like primary metal-lurgyc 
There is thus every reason to make the opposite assumption, 
that of a zero correlation between organic composition 
and departmental classification. 

G-iven this assumption it follows that the average 
organic composition is virtually equal in the two depart- 
ments. In this case, of course, the product of each 
department would have a total price equal to its total 
value, and all relationships expressed in average (i.e., 
aggregative) terms between the departments would be absolute- 
ly unaltered. The equilibriixm of simple reproduction would 
not be disturbed, and the system as a whole would be 

internally consistent o 

Is the foregoing a satisfactory reply to these 
theoretical criticisms? For most practical purposes it 
undoubtedly is, at least as far as the basic Marxian 
aggregates are concernedo However, from a theoretical 
standpoint it is inadequate for two reasons: first of all, 
even if it is most improbable that organic composition 
should be correlated with departmental classification, it 



239 



is still theoretically possible, so that if the Marxian 
system is generally valid It must also hold in this 
special case: and second, every specific industry requires 
different material elements for its constant and variabl-^ 
capital, so that it by no means follows that if in the 
aggregate these coirmiodities are sold at their values this 
will be true for the industry in question. Accordingly 
the expansion of the simple-reproduction scheme into an 
input-output type table for the entire economy is 
essentially a development from the two sector model in 
which values and prices of production are unequal in each 

department. 

For these reasons, then, it is necessary to show 
directly the applicability of Marx's method of transforming 
values into prices of production to the two sector model 
with systematically differing organic compositions in the 
two departments. To do this it is necessary to be clear 
on the exact significance of the category "value" in this 

model. 

As we saw, the direct objection to Marx's trans- 
formation formula was that in going from the value of a 
commodity, c 4- v + s, to its price of production, c + v + p, 
it allows only for the ch.ange between s and £, leaving c 

and V the same, 

Marx, for his part, was well aware that "Since the 
price of production may vary from the value of a commodity. 



240 



it follows that the cost-price of a commodity containing 
this price of production may also stand above or below 
that portion of its total value which is formed by the 
value of the means of production [including labor-power^ 
s.m,] consumed by ito"^ He did not, however, consider this 
to contradict his transformation formula"^ as expressed in 
the statement that: '''A capitalist selling his commodities 
at their price of production recovers money in proportion 
to the value of the capital consumed in their production 
and secures profits in proportion to the aliquot part 
which his capital represents in the total social capitalo"3 

These two citations, however, certainly seem 
contradictory, .and Marx nowhere attempts a specific 
resolution of this contradiction. It is nevertheless 
possible to demonstrate that the contradiction is merely 
apparent, and to do so in a manner implicitly indicated 
by Marx's formulations themselves. 

The key is to be found in the fact that in his 
general formulation Marx speaks of " the value of the capital 
consumed in . , . production" ("die Vfertgrosse des in der 



1. Capital , III, 19I4-. 

2o Cf. Capital , III, 2i].2, where Marx specifically reaffirms 
the proposition that all comjnodities produced by capitals 
of average composition will have prices of production equaj. 
to their values, 

3o Capital , III, l87o 



241 



Produktion von ihm verzehrten Kapitals"-^) while in dis- 
cussing the supposed secondary deviation from value he 
refers to "the value of the means of production consumed" 
C^der Wert der in sie eingehenden Produktionsmittel"^) o 
The crucial point is to understand that these are different 
quantities. 

As we saw at the outset, for Marx " Capital is not 
a thing " - it is a social relationshipo The "things" 
through which this relationship bet'ween people is expressed 
are defined specifically as capital only by that role - 
they are not capital in themselves. 

It is here that Marx's differentiation between the 
two primary forms of circulation, C-M-C and M-C-M', takes 
on central importancsc In C-M-G value is passive ^ a mere 
"equivalent form," reflecting the immanent attributes of 
commodities as products of social laboro For that reason 
this form of circulation is quite Independent of the mode 
of production, as valid for a primitive as for a capitalist 
society. 

On the contrary, value is " the active factor " in 
the M-C-M' circuit, in which the physical object is merely 
"a disguised mode of existence" of " value itself ." M-C-M' 
is "the general formula for capital " precisely because the 



lo Das Kapital, III, iSIj. 
2, Ibid. , p. 190. 



242 



capitalist mode of production is essentially characterized 
by tHe self -expansion of value. Hence the "value" of a 
thing has a radically different meaning depending on 
whether it is as a use-value part of the social final 
product, the end of a C=.M-C process; or x.hether it is 
an intermediary stage in an M-G-M' circuit: in other v^ords, 
whether it is viewed as coimnodity or as capital o 

The essential error of Sweezy and Bortkiewicz is that 
when they ask "how much value does this capital good trans- 
fer to the product?" they answer "its own value as deter- 
mined at the time of its production." But in this way they 
sLmply negate its character as capital - they treat the 
production of value as a relationship among things, not 

a.mong people. 

As constant or variable capital the "capital good" 
according to Marx is nothing but the "disguised form" of 
"value itselfo" At the extremes of the M-G-M' process 
"value itself" stands out in its general form, as pure 
money. The "capital good," as a disguise for the money, 
can transfer to its product only the value for Trjhic h it 
stands , only the value-equivalent of its actual monetary 
cost to the capitalist who uses it* If he paid for it at 
more or less than its value this, as Marx states, is of 
absolutely no consequence to him so long as it really cost 
the prevailing market price. The difference between the 
value created by its production and its price of production 



243 



has already been transferred to other capitalists through 
the average rate of profit. Henceforth, "however scurvy 
.it may look," it is really "in faith and truth money . . o 
and a wonderful means whereby out of money to make more 

moneyo" 

Accordingly, in the Marxian formulae c + v + s 
and c + v + p, c and v are indeed value expressions: they 
express the value of the capital consuraed, and Sweezy is 
dead wrong to take Marx to task for treating them as such. 
This does not, of course, imply that they are independe-nt 
of the transformation of values into prices of production, 
that is, of capitalist production itself I On the contrary, 
they, and the quantitative relationships based upon them, 
must be regarded as determined by the total process of 
capitalist production, a process in which the formation of 
prices of production is an essential parte 

On the basis of this approach, identifying "cost 
price" to the value of capital consumed, it is now possible 
to test Marx's transformation method in the case of a two- 
sector economy in which each department is treated as a 
separate industry having its own characteristic organic 
composition of capital. 

The general model"'- of simple reproduction in this 



1 It is simple, not expanded, reproduction which represents 
the o-eneral case of macro-economic eauilibrium. Expanded 
reproduction along an equilibriim path requires merely alter- 
ation of equations III and VII in accordance with the unique 
rate of growth of income and capital stock. In this case 



244 



case, with)!-^, Xg* ^'' ^"^^ * ^^ parameters, consists of 

jquations in seven variables (Z^, %£, J?]^* ^2*' Tl^ ^2* ®-^ 



seven 



I qAiVi (1 + s')t + v^d + ^is') = Zi0i 

II Q;j2V2(1 + s')t + VgCl +/^2^') = ^2^2 
(determination of prices of production in the two 

departments) 

III y^d + s'Ai) = Q^2^2^1 + s')t 
(simple reproduction) 



IV 



V ri + sM (1 + Q^-t) = z, 
1 i j- 



V V2(l + s') (1 + Q)i2t) = ^2 
(determination of values in the tvjo departments) 

VI 1j^0i + Z2^2 = ^1 "^ ^-2 

(aggregate identity between value and price of production) 

VII Zt + Z2 = P_i 

(total value of gross product determined and constant) 

By substitution and elimination this reduces to 
three equations: 



la Q)ii(l + s')t + (1 + -^is') = (1 + sM (1 + Q.\t)0j_ 

lia (1 ^^.-.oM . (1 ->->>l3M d-^Aps') , (i^;^^3,)(i 

t0.^2(l ■*• s') 1 . 

Ilia (1 + sMd + QAit)j^i + (1 + )\is')(l + 'C^)^2 = 
(1 + sMd + Q>iit) + (1 + ^isMCi + -^) 



(Qj_=: Q2), Equation III x^ould be: vi(l + sMi) - 
Q?l2V2(l + s')t + Qr(v3_ + V2) d + s')* 



245 



Solving for 0i and 02 ^® £®^ ^^^ ex'pression already 

derived, _____XI^II 
^^ 1 + QXit 

Once the numerical value of Q is determined the 
values of the other variables are easily obtained. Thfl 
total result is a solution to the "transformation problem" 
in v'hich the prices of production are derived in the way 
indicated by Marx; in which the equilibrium of simple 
reproduction is maintained both in terms of price and of 
physical assets; and in which the overall total of prices 
is equal to the total of values. 

The significance of this solution, like that of 
any equilibri^jm B^odel, is largely formal: it shows that 
the Marxian categories are self-consistent, that the formal 
system contains no internal inconsistency, no logical 
contradiction* It is therefore justified to treat observable 
economic aggregates as representatives of the corresponding 
Marxian categories, even though most individual price 
relationships deviate from tbeir equilibrium levels. This 
is of particular importance for the rate of profit which 
has meaning only as a relationship between aggregates^ 



246 



APPENDIX B 

SUPPIEI^NTARY TO CHAPTER VI 



Note: Sources for these Tables are descrlbecl in the 
section of Chapter VI on Sources and Methods . 



247 



TABIE B - I 
PRICE INUEX (195U = 100) 

Year Index 2®H l£^ 

1900 28o20 

1901 28«20 

1902 29.ii? 



A.-P1JJ 



31.26 

190U 30.6U 

1905 30,6lt 

1906 31.87 

1907 35.71 

1908 31.87 

1909 31.87 

1910 33.71 

1911 33.71 

1912 36.16 

1913 35.55 
191U 36.06 

1915 36*U8 

1916 39.16 

1917 U6.05 

1918 5U.0U 

1919 62 0x8 

1920 72o02 

1921 6k.21 

1922 60.17 

1923 61.26 
192U 6lJ*3 

1925 63.03 

1926 63.53 

1927 62.36 

1928 61,60 

1929 61.60 



1930 


59oOO 


1931 


52.60 


1932 


U6.50 


1933 


liit,30 


I93I1 


li7.60 


1935 


U806O 


1936 


U9.10 


1937 


50o90 


1938 


U9.80 


1939 


li9.20 


19ii0 


U9.70 


19U1 


53.10 


19i+2 


59o5o 


191*3 


65.00 


19ljli 


68^60 


19U5 


71.00 


19U6 


76.50 


19ii7 


81;»60 


19ii8 


89.50 


19lt9 


680 70 


1950 


89.90 


1951 


96.00 


1952 


98.00 


1953 


99.00 


195U 


100.00 


1955 


100.1iO 


1956 


102,20 


1^7 


105-10 


1958 


107.30 


1959 


108o50 


I960 


110,10 



Sources described in Chapter VI, Section HI, (p. 177) 



248 



Table B-H, Capital stock, I900-I96O (Millions of GwsQnt Dollars) 



ygar 



■^aT 

Producer 

Durable 

EgtiilBBant 



TBT 



BusiZBSS 

structures 



■~T5r- — 

Fu9l and 
Mineral 
DeTOlepnsnt 
^penditurss 



JdT 



luvsatoriss 



JiT- 



Total 



1900 

1 
2 

■a 

h 
5 
6 

7 
8 
9 
1910 
1 
2 
3 
k 
5 
6 

7 
8 
9 
1920 
1 
2 
3 
h 
5 
6 
7 
8 
o 

1930 

1 

2 

3 

h 

S 

6 

7 

8 

9 
19W) 



5238.5 
552Uo7 
5906*1 
65U6,1 
6625.7 
6890.9 
7625.9 
86ii6cl 
8Uh7o6 
8529.9 

9it89.7 
101*62,5 
10761.8 
1120li.5 

II501.U 
126ii7.U 

16553*ii 

21262.6 

25811.8 

30I472.9 

27175.1 

25252.6 

26233.li 

27098.ii 

281i21,3 

29378.9 

29iaj7.? 

29611.5 

30589.U 

30021.1 

26U70.8 

22U51.0 

20527.5 

2l055o5 

tfi.^x7.i> 

22081,0 

2ii059.0 
2h2kka 
2/a82,7 
255U1;.5 



12576.3 
13070.5 
13631.1 
2ii783o9 
ll*726«U 
1U993.S 
I6003oli 
17U59*9 
16960.9 
17385oU 

19255»8 
21014,3 
21I6I1.8 
21896<»0 

221*30.9 
2l4U79,0 
293U9*9 
31*910.8 
lt05U3.1 

IJ285i.8 
lj0532.U 
Ij2102.6 
U3390.5 
U5851.U 
lt?86»..? 
Ii8801o6 
1*991*6.1* 
51766.7 
51131.2 
1*6083.1* 
1*0305.7 
38008.1 

39399a 
39512.1* 
39^3.8 
li051*9.2 
39519.6 
38760.0 
39lOi..8 



522.8 
51*8.6 

571**9 
631.8 

61*0.9 
661.1 

712.5 

786ili 

773.1 

800.9 

877«8 

905.7 

1010c2 

1036.2 

1100.3 

1151.9 

1301*.J 

1670.8 

2152.1* 

2656.1 

■JVlC. A 

3121*. 3 
3029.2 
3219.8 
3361*.!* 
5591.8 
3788.6 
3851.0 
3875.2 

3953.7 
3860.6 
31*31.9 
3018.2 
2895.7 
3066c 2 

3171.5 
329l».lt 
3590,6 
3698sU 
380i*.0 
1*011,6 



5339 
5370 
5590 
5951 
5815 
5891* 
6U55 
7053 
721D 

731*7 
7832 

8053 
8268 
8888 

ns^ 

96U5 
11865 
I6087 
19960 
2U01*7 

fsn\.£.r> 

25382 
23362 
25683 
2701*1 
27570 

^0X00 

27992 

27531* 
27909 

261*71 
22106 
17832 
16506 
17692 
16556 
2031*ij 
22699 
221*77 
21960 
23632 



23677 

2i*511* 

25708 

27913 

27808 

281*1*0 

3079? 

3391*5 

33392 

3itf)63 

36820 

37701* 

1*0785 

ia85l 

1*31*50 

1»1*729 

50296 

63661 

78306 

93058 

xyjofyx 

9853^ 

92176 

97239 

100891* 

1051*3U 

109220 

110092 

110967 

111*219 

1111*81* 

98092 

83598 

77937 

81313 

82557 

65023 

90898 

89939 

88707 

92293 



Table B-II. (continued) 



249 



(a) 



(b) 



Cc) 



(d) 



Ce) 



19kl 


29312.1i 


U2102,7 


UU82.5 


28273 


10M71 


2 


33808,5 


U719it.8 


5152.1 


32952 


119108 


3 


36195 •ii 


50619»5 


5680.3 


3li239 


126698 


U 


37882,8 


52211.5 


6128.7 


3U306 


130529 


5 


li052Uo2 


53251.6 


6566,8 


3k23h 


131^577 


6 


ii6950.i; 


58565.5 


7316,6 


U0930 


153762 


7 


57931.it 


67921.7 


8375.1 


51923 


166151 


8 


68753.1 


75000.8 


9300,5 


59026 


212080 


9 


7li086,0 


77091.6 


9729.6 


59531 


220U38 


1950 


81025.1 


8o837o2 


10ii30.3 


63297 


235590 


1 


91298.6 


8986U,8 


ll885.i; 


7U618 


267667 


2 


98935-9 


95872.1i 


12i|81.2 


80391 


287680 


3 


1051^28.7 


I0lit06.6 


U056,5 


61990 


302882 


li 


111203.1 


10737U.5 


152ii5.ii 


82225 


3l60i;8 


5: -: 


r;1163i|1.9 


ll,3361io9 


16!;69.7 


8505U 


331251 


6 


125U55.1 


122131.2 


18958.8 


92899 


35851jU 


7 


137689.9 


133518.6 


19752,1 


9835U 


389315 


8 


11|5672,5 


lii3520.7 


20957.8 


98398 


koBSh? 


9 


11|9878.7 


151330.8 


2185Uo8 


100657 


U23721 


1960 


156535.1 


160237.5 


22871.5 


105972 


iai56l6 



250 



n^ableB-III. Cai^ital Cons-umption. 1900-1950 (Millions of Current 

Dollars) 





(a) 


(1)) 


(c) 

Fuel and 


(d) 




Producer 




Mineral 






Dursole 


Business 


Development 




year 


3nui-Dment 


Structure s 


Sx'oenditures 


Total 


1900 


540.9 


513.3 


33.0 


1087.2 


1 


564.3 


553.5 


54.6 


1132.4 


2 


604.3 


556.4 


35.5 


1197,0 




674.3 


603.4 


59.9 


1317.5 


A 


580.0 


501.1 


40.7 


1321.8 


5 


708.0 


612.0 


41.9 


1361.9 


6 


785.9 


653.2 


45.1 


1484.3 


7 


894.0 


712.6 


49.9 


1656.5 


8 


878.7 


592.3 


49,1 


1620.1 


9 


896.5 


709.6 


51.2 


1657.3 


1910 


980.4 


769.6 


56.2 


1805.2 


1 


1011.3 


785.7 


58.1 


xouo.i 


2 


. 1118.5 


859.0 


64.6 


2042.1 


1 


1158.0 


853.9 


67.0 


2088.9 


4 


1217.1 


895.7 


71.7 


2182.5 


5 


1259.5 


915.5 


75.3 


2250.4 


6 


1449.9 


999.1 


35.6 


2534.5 


7 


1914.0 


1198.0 


110.5 


3222.3 


8 


2525.4 


1424.9 


143.2 


4094.5 


9 


3105.9 


1654.8 


178.4 


4940.1 


1920 


3660.4 


1940.6 


224.5 


5825.6 


1 


3232.5 


1749.1 


214.4 


5195.0 


2 


2978.2 


1654.4 


209. 3 


4841.9 


3 


3123.9 


1718.5 


223.3 


5066.2 


A_ 


3252.6 


1771.0 


234.9 


5258.5 


5 


3468.5 


1871.5 


252.4 


5592.4 


5 


3511.7 


1953.7 


268.1 


5833.5 


7 


3554.8 


1991.9 


273. B 


5900.5 


8 


3660.5 


2038.6 


276.3 


5975.4 


9 


3825.4 


2112.9 


282.6 


6220.9 


1930 


3766.3 


2087.0 


276.8 


6130.1 


1 


3275.5 


1881.0 


245.5 


5403.0 


2 


2721.5 


1645.1 


216.9 


4585.5 


3 


2445.5 


1551.4 


208.4 


4206.3 


4 


2509.6 


1612.2 


221.1 


4342.9 


5 


2572.9 


1612.8 


229.5 


4415.2 


G 


2745.0 


1604.2 


239.4 


4588.5 


7 


3063.4 


1655.1 


262.5 


4981.6 


8 


3093.8 


1613.0 


272.0 


4978.8 


9 


3084.7 


1532.0 


281.2 


4947.9 


1940 


3294.8 


1596.1 


297.5 


5188.4 



251 



Ta'ble 


B-r-III. (continued) 








year 


(a) 


(b) 


(c) 


(d) 


1941 


S829.3 


1718.5 


333.2 


5881.0 


2 


4292.6 


1926.3 


282.8 


5601.7 


3 


4329.5 


2066.1 


420.9 


6816.5 


A 


4364.4 


2131.1 


453.9 


6949.4 


5 


4649.0 


2173.5 


487.2 


7309.7 


6 


5605.8 


2390.4 


544.3 


8540.5 


7 


7295.9 


2772.7 


624.6 


10683.2 


8 


8922.9 


3061.3 


695.7 


12679.9 


9 


9714.4 


3146,6 


730 c 8 


13591.8 


I95C 


10587,2 


3299.5 


786.9 


14673.6 


1 


12155.7 


3668.0 


900.8 


16724.5 


2 


15087.5 


3913.2 


988.5 


17989.2 


3 


13805.1 


4139.0 


1075.7 


19019.8 


4, 


14411.3 


4382.8 


1172.6 


19966.7 


5 


14989.1 


4627.1 


1274.4 


20890.6 


6 


16253.6 


4984.9 


1401.2 


22639.7 


7 


1793912 


5449.7 


1536.8 


24925.7 


8 


18829. 8 


5858.0 


1633.3 


26321.1 


9 


19156.9 


6176.8 


1705.6 


27039.3 


1960 


19935.5 


6540.3 


1787.4 


28263.2 



252 



10 



«3 



to 



tOa)-«aOlCJli^MMI-'0«3CO-<!CD01i^03COM o 



HOMI-'iPili.MNMtDO 
« OJ *> &5 00 to it^ M cn 0^ w 






M M M M &J £0 
Ol H to SJ M cn 



^ 



H" ^3 ^5 H H M w 
CDMMtOOJCOOM 



«oo^MW(j3cnoo30cn^^a)Mcr)to^3;>a cd 
^-'^5^>■^IOtti>c^l«>wo^-'Ml^M->3cno oo 



OltPwWHHcOOOO-OCDOltOtOOtpCDCXl-OOl-^Cn . 

0><SoJO>0>C.ICOC31C;l^-'MI-'CFll>HOCnc;l^5-v3C^IO^t^^Dl>M^O__ 

if»M&3MM05Ho^i-'&3Mcn-<itoo>if>.ifkOMa3-5taM''ait^«T>ocn 



on 1^. yi Oi ;^ !^ tJ^ 

lF» to lP> M to it* M 



01 



HMHHHHHM 

o^cx)OlWMM^^&^ 

OOHit^HUlOH-CI 



HoocD->2->3^-JSiS!CT><T>CT>CTia>05cnoitnoic;ioi 
i-'t^Wtpr^o>MH'O!5<02i^£0Ht£>-^cni.^WH 



MOOWMtOOlMOCn 



CD ^ 

« 05 



<£( H 1^- ^3 ("J 01 00 &3 



Ototoiototooaoi 

OtOtDQOSJOlMtO 
OlMMi^OlOlOCTl 



iti'OlC.JCTiCOOiOlcnaiSI-NlStMMCOCJiMtOHClOOO 
00->300Cri->J«00«J«DOOO)OOrfii>CD&3i>Cn0105<0 



cyiMO^HO^£)a>o^o^MO^o•^a^J^3^-'^-»o«DtooocD-acftq50iOlpl*» 

-«3«>O<J3tf'00rf>-CJl ^3C^I-ClC;l^3^0i^50000lt0^f5»-^J«gJ^D|^Og}HOO 

oiaiotoMoooiw to-OMH-aoosooitOMOicnH-'OtoKi ooaioicji 



M I 



I I I I 

I t> M H H CO ^^ i 



CJlM^oH^-»o>Olooc>J^^ol^3!j^H^ k 

OJ-^Ja>HOil^>■MO^^3W£0«3<X>^-•l^■-vI^t: 



S III 

^^ i^ I M M M M I 

cocnMi^--aoHH-ai^cnM 

CJ)0iO-<(0^Orfb.0iW0iC001 




a 



tJ bd o 
fi O O 
o 



^^t 



Vi 


o 


£B 


Hj 


H 


•-^ 


P) 


H- 


^J 


O 


H- 


CD 


O 


•^ 


ca 


a 






w is; 

et- 



O O 

Id 

03 M 



ts 



-=4 w 

H- O 



Hj 



■< Cfl P 
P P! 4 
H »i O '- 

fi *5d CO C) 
CD h» ca ">- 

P 

en 

I 



w 

•=5 



a 
I 



to 
o 

CJ 

I 

H 
CD 
CJ> 
O 



H 

H 

O 

o 
o 



4 

<D 
P 
el- 

o 



vi 



255 



H H M l-» H 

tjD yj to to ID 

C51 CJl 1?^ M W 

OtOOOKJCr. 01i^-MWMOtOOO^a>01*'OJIWr-'0<OCD->ICnoii!^MMHOtD 



^_l^_l(_JH^-'l-'HH^-'^-'^^l-'HH i 

<X)C00100tJ^tDC^Il^^P>•CnOtr)CDCn^5•>3tOtOOOOOC;^(^M^^.^^5•Mt-' &3 I co^ 

1-n ij r^ r.T ^1 .f^ rrs to rji rn (-> -.7 ui f Ti (■•> h^ l-i .K -o> -O to Ol to en 05 li^ 00 M tl^ 00 M H 

CTJto ocnto->a£oto oo^3^!^o^ 

cjicxj oicnwwoM ooojoj 



<X)COCnOOtOtDC^Il^•^>•C7lO<r)CDCn^5•>3tOtOOOOO 

ooMOw<! iti.o>toM o^o-clHtJ^ow^-'!^ -<!•<? 

C/1 !-• M M C-3 -nJ i!^ C? M M rf^ ■<! •<! to tn H (01 to M -0 






a 

& 



tri 

I 

M 



UJ UJ L^ 

WHOtotooo-^3■<!■<I-<lcno1Ulo^l^(yl&3c^IC^i^o^^^)^5M^^^-'^-'HH^3coM 
o^3Mto^3cnc;lM^-'Ocnoo^D(>}OlOl^^^3^3tOlp>•wt-■w^3^)coa1-c!Hwol 

it^O->3i;iOOMCJlCnM(7lHa50MOCnO>->3£OCO-<JM!^'-sZa5CJlO&3H'-ai--'03 
tj!«tOOlOOHCnOiIiMMW-N!0500->JOCDrf!>05^tOtOOO^tDHOCOtO'<!->30 



o 

o 

(D 



MWEOtOiO HMI MH" I HHHMl-'-HHI-'MHMMHHt-'H 

C0->3 l^^^O tX)->3Cn|t»MGJtDI-'H'WMWtfi-i>ili.CnOlO>O>->3C0->3OlUl 
OMO->3a)tnOUlO&3(^S2Om05|fc.a30lMM-at0CJ10Ji}>>P01ili'&3 
^^•-^3 if>.02M ^-'M^Mt0^b.M^f!>005&JtOtOtD|>tDC^IC31M^5^3C^!tOiO 



t?^ M M M W CO tO iO 
M CD Ol -■ - - '--^ 
M to cn „ 

Ol H -O ^^ 



M M M W M 

I> CO 



M &3H 

. _ M CD Ol W OtO 

M CD O CO H O -<2<! 



i-'t-'Hi-'i-'h'i-'i-' 




H M 


00-<3C;i(^.l{5.MHOtO 


oo-ao>05C3>o^cjic;icjioiM 


->3 M M 


owtocrit^ooicocn 


O Ul 05 


SIOtOODHOlOISIOl 


^i-<l-'ip.tO0000Hi>l-'(J> 


00 H oa 



CO 



^3 to CO CO M M l-'M 
M CO M O 00 ->3 t>.M 
to Ol O M 03 W OOH 
l-» CJl 00 ^ oa H tOi^ 
CO Cn O i|i. &3 CO COM 



l-'O00->3-<3Ul!p>.0lOltf«(>i^MMMMC>lMMMMMv>M 
v^O-CIOOO-NZCnCOI-'OiMOOiOlt^-CnJ^WMi^CnooOtD 
CO-NjOMCDOaMOltOODtOCOCOHPMOOiH'MOl-aOOQ 
rJWWHMOtO■^J-^Iti^:f»^3-^3COCOMtOH03^-'0^300 



I I t I I t I i 

. ,^ _. tDHtOCOl-'COtOUlCO^COi^CO-JtOt -OCOOOf-'Oi?^. COrf^ 

vDtT' CiMtO&JI-'tO OOtOO-. O^UltDa>OlO^-JO-C10HO>03C^lCOCO*>^f'H05-^J 

tOCnaitoc.io)Co->3»-'toc;io2CotoMif»^Mi?iH'Oifi'Wi-'oo-^oic>a->3»tiOco 



: I I 
I I M CO H I - 

Hi^COtnOl-JMtO 



H, 



en U! Ol CJl Ol i?^ i> « 

RjODCJoaoooooD 

H'CnOMiF'-i^H'CJI 
-O -0 O CO (M O CO 03 

if^cOHOotocn-'Jci 



&30q&3COC<qtOi-JH}-'»-'f=»l-'l-'l-»t->HM 

->3OiH00l-'CO0300tOC0^C;iCOHHCOI-«tO00 

05HC^IH<(^OCn^^^^^&^tD-^I^{i.■^3CJl-^2CO 



COOOCJOi-JCJlCrstDt^eOM 
^tOrfi.-Cf-vICn-J-sISICnM 



criH(i>coc;icr>too 

^^•tOCO^-•<i-<!Cn-^3 



t-J M H 

CJl o en en 

rfi ->3 !-• to 

en ips 03 M 

en < CJl en 



m 



254 



*:i *-' H 

M g S 

-<!cr)cn ii^M CO MO r£)Co-v3cn en l^w^3^-•o 10 co-<i cr. aii^wftiMO 



,-v, r,> rr. ,c^ r.-, UJ n^ ro o CO H Ol -nJ ,t^ H ,f^ S N S O -5 CD M H S M S 5 
OCn-C!tDCa-vj-v2Cn(-'HCDOlOJ->3C71Ul(->0-<!Cyi 



IXI tiJ CD iP' 05 (-' 00 tD 
COOT. COODJOCO^OI 



i-' M H' M H M M 

^' O; ife M M kN 03 O) to M CO O) CO O ^ 03 M S ^5 Oi ^ j^ M H o § S S 



to CO C>J fO CO CO t-iH 
Ol M oq CO CO CO -QC1 
CD to 03 i[^ CD O OICD 



M H H M M M H 
03C^l^-^2-^3tOCOCD-CI^CO-<!005HOiO^^CTJH 



CO (X ■<z a- -J -^a -oto 
CO CO «D o -a en com 
Co oi «3 en t-" O'' to en 



CO Cr. Ul CJI (ti. if:. .. 
H t.0 CO 03 to CD Ol 
-^3 i— ■ UJ ifi M CD 01 



ti 03 1,*^ il=- l^ G3 03 M M M 03 Oa Oq « 

i-'co»-'toto^a>lF=-ii^coi-'o 



to 



->3-NZOI-'Cn63{\30t0 01fOtO 



I 



o: H CO if>- 

->3 CO to H 



i r-' t-" I i M (-' t 

CO 00 H-i CJl Oi W M CO 
|t> !-> O CO Ol CJl !-■ O 

rt^woicntoi-'toco 



M ^5 

MHO 
M -sj ->3 



I i I 

, H CO . I M I M CO I 

01->3tOMCJ)C1MtOCnWa503 
tO&3MCX)CnfOil:.OlMOMi> 



^0.63HMi53i^S^^^!i^B^5!3b;t::HHMMMMMH 
CO^CT»COO:;Cn!03C003MOlCT>-v3 



I-' }-> h-* 



O! c;i oi 01 cn ii^ 

Ot0 01MC3CX)03Ma)C75,^MCJlMOaMC00103ai-^OOroCjl!SSoo 



MMOq^a^g^OOOtOCpbo^blCnbil^MMlOCOM 
Cr>03Cin^COMMi?^-<3O5i|s-CIo^ai.[_i 



COCOC0C0MC0i>t-3MM MMMMMMMMMMMMi-jmuj<-j 

v'SH£"i°?^*''yit^C)CD^CT>00CTiCOO>-Nl&3OlSM^O3,NMCOC.-3 

oo^olo^M,^tDo^,^co&300D-^Ito-^^o^30rfi.o^^^McoMMootn 



CD 
4 



t3 O 

O M 

a oj 

CD 



W O 

O (D 

P 

O 



2) 



tD W 
P a- 



J> << 


M 


p. p 





L-r* 


M <J 




1 


CD 


ch 


c*- 


c*- 


s 


H* 


O 


a> 


O 


^ 


c+ 






fcd 


-^ 


^ t^ 


g 


(^ 


4 (D 
O 03 


H- 


m >ci CO 


< 




H •. 


P 




H" 


M 




(S 


O 




<rt- 






^ 



a> 



H> 



;S^ £P '•^ 

PJ P 4 
M 4 O 

pJ tJ ra 

O M C3 

H 



(I»3 



H3 

g- 



I 



O 

o 

4 

O 
4 
03 
c*- 

O 

ra 

H- 
P 

O 

0) 

ra 
P 

4 
O 

TO 

01 

4 

CO 

I 

-=5 

P 



i?' 





CD 

1 




1 

1-3 




03 










/-*> 


M 


s 


to 


M 


O 


M 


o 


*_J 


• 






M 


M 


O 


CO 


P 


en 


ta 


o 



>-b 



4 
(D 
P 

t) 
O 



4 

Kl 



255 



H 


















M 


to 


















CD 


o> 


















Ol 


O 


<i) 


Co 


-a 


c^ 


ai 


v> CJ 


w 


H 


O 



CO 



10 CO -Ci ai CTi iF' M ^3 H 



§.o 



CK ->3 en CT-^ W 



M O W W CO i^ -^ to it^ 05 O 03 O i!^ H CD H W cr M en Ul -3 H g -^ M W 
OWOOTOa503Wi^OHCOv!^CJlH'-CiCnCOMOO-^3MWWt^05CDO^ 







H 




H 


^ 


1-3 






tD 




U) 


© 


S, 






Ol 




o:) 


re 


a" 


w 


H 


o 


10 


03 


H 


W 
1 









COM W Ol 
COCO ->2 fO 



0-. 

CO 



CJltnCni?5.-'^M&qMMMCUC0Wl--'HHHMH'HHMH'HI--'t--'Ht--'MJ--'HHM 

HOoSekiS§^wwS^SSwa^w-vi-3-<3a^o>o(^OT9m-3mco«3Co-^ 

^raHmScoS-OtOO«DH03^<!OlCnCO-<!gU)i^MH-550 0^OTCTCOW.!^t« 
SMOMMO^O^MCOl^cD^D^3(-'^OC>3«^^50BO&5Crla>^^^-'Cn>cDfO^^-aC.Il■<3^-^ 



^ CJ Ol en tn ,t^ Ct3 M 03 03 CO CO H' M H M H M W PJ C\3 CO CO H CO M W CO W y W M to 
Ha^MH-5t^C^C0W-3w0)MC0O-t>0lM0iai*HC0i^caC0tDCD0iC7ia>O.t> 



M M M 5 ^ S K M M M M H h^ '-D CO cr; 01 Ul tr. O) Ol en ai 01 Ol CI CJl ti^ en -C! a TO p^ 
^ O^ ^ W Ol O W ^ M to 5 M O ^O en 05 CD ai 01 OJ r-" H' tD H W ,^ W Ol 03 -S^ 1^ ;>3 M 



I 



1 Ml MUIMI MCOOlOl>il='iP'<Il-'l H&301I J-iCOl Ml I OlWC^^il-' 
HSoiOoSj^a^OWtO^M^OOOUlOH.^CrjfJCOWyiOlWtDHC^^ 
Soa^OCOOoSoOH-0>f^OI01-'0-CntDCT-vI010-10^MtDOOi>01Cni-'OlCO.t>- 



COCOCOfJCOCOHH'Mi-'HHI-'l-'H 
CTiCJlMMC0OtD03->3CD01iri-03C0O00-a-<2-aC-. 
iIi.C1-OHOiF'MOOCDCOM03tD->2 0lMO>MOH 
H!-■tOCJlCn-<I0030^l!^COO-^ICOCOC003-<l^^tO 
MC^cO03t-•03COa^^f>■<DGIC0CDC0^D^-'^^l^-^O^ 



Ol W Ol Ol '> (i» (l^ ;!^ '> Ol 01 CT) Ol 
Ol03HHC;01C00 0103CDO-v! 
-<3cD:^~aHl-'-JMMI-'C0C0Cr) 
-vIjt^->3-v3C001-'M01CDCDi^Cn 



01 CiJ en 
Ol ix: o 



:0 CO CO CO M M H M M W 

ta.MMMOlCOCO 03 030tO 
MO->3HCOCr. ^3MW^^O3P0^JWC^O5OiMCD-<2HtOHl^WtpMCntDM 
^OOMOO^Ot^WOiO^-'CDtO|N<OCOH-^3l^l^OtDCr>-^3l-'C>00^00 



01->2->3COCa->3-C-<JOD03-Cl-NjSlCricOti)COtOC?101M 
cO6ai^C065-CII-'i|^O-0Wt00303fJcOC0 03tpOM 



o 



255 



i-> i^ i^ 

^, ^ ^ vo 

^3^0I^^no^^ro^^|-JHf-'^-J'-'HHH'-'H O 

O'^-P"^ r\>H ovo oo-j o'^ ■t'Vo roHOMDCB-aoNVnp-ujroHO 

l-'i-'\-'i-'h-'i-'h-'t-> H 

^^ ■prEi V^ O O \jj Hvo O coovjT.ovAvn.vJT.^fr-j::-4r-^Vjjfr-ujVjo ro 
-J H4='0 U) gpvo O 4="r\3vovjT.-j (>o vn.i:r-o-^ vn-o vjj o 0\i-< oo \o 
O^ °?OTfiJ-^C>^^°°'^^-'T-'^^^'^'^5 On&-->3VjJ CO od od cofrvo co-ou> 
OS OVAO->3--0 rOH-aU)OH^OOH ON^^O"OC»4:r-OvoVD-O^Vn 



'^ >h;. Si? V^ C^ *-* ^^-i-J os^ O rovD OT H4=" oons-o Ocoroo->3ro04r- 
v^^O^^-'4=-\ovn.4r-fo\JJOCn-^ovo-JOf^J04:r■VJJr^^^^^oVJOHC»\?l 



l-J'r-'i-'h'h-'Hi-'i-'h'Hh-'y-'}-' 



H HHMMHHHHH 

CO C>VA4^rovri-^roOOvo03-~j-^ON-^-OOsO\C>vJT.vn.4::rvjT.£r-ir-fr- 

-0 oso vo n\ ro jjj .rr-4r-\o ONro CJsvo -si ovno H HuavTwo oas ro ro 

V'-] \ n K ^ S !^ *-^ v"^ °° 2 'i' f-* ^ayf -JcxjvnvoONVocNOvn-JOODCo 

(-j^AHHi-'CN-JVn.vooNOvoovn.coo-^iOVjJHorocoMcoroo 



o oooooooool 
ro ro'ooUJ^j\ujUj'JT.c»'jiJ 
+: — J ro O O 'sJT 'wT. \n. o Hi 



ro ro ro ro M ro M H H Hi 

->a Os^JT. vn.->j H m o o CM 
O vnoT. H C3 -J o c-vji-o| 



■ I I 



I I 



i I 



O OOOOOOOHOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 

H:fc^t;^^°='2>'^9 HVJT.OCrVnioO-<lt-H ON4:r-U)^P^ONH^ONro 
CO OON-p-vo OvoO-<iU>UT.ro4r-H OOOnVJvo H -j -<l ■<) |:r--j ij ro 



H }-ih-> h-i h-i -r-i h-> Y-' 

->] "iJi ^^ UJ H £- o\ H ^o vo M3 -<i -0 -0 o^o-ovn*JT.vn\nUT.p-vj-ii:r-j:r-£r- 
vn 4^-^ °o-ErO ro\jL) h^ouj^w ouicoUi ca^vovjjUj-ojr-cKHH 
H ~v^"-0 ro 1^ ij\4_ — o O-o ro w coot rofr" H --3 4^ Co ^3 H -^ ^ fr- roc" 
co vcivnvjj HvooHcoo-oo3VA\jo-oHcx)Hcn oCo Hvn^Hvnrb 



*^ >JJvJT.^^>oivn.jr-4r-uj roro rororoHHHHHMHHHHHH 

F° ^I^ OraHCDVOOrOVArOHOOCDCOONOONE-CjCjGHHO 

t— • — ^»-' v^^ I w v^» v> * \^ xrf V 1 V V k \_* vjw >tj i\.r >^ ^ w^— >j 'w' *^ 4-^ fo ro 03"^ ro— *3 



H H 

CT\^^A->3 0\034r-|r-0-0~J On rO UT ~vo vJT. rO Ui \jO CO vo rr H -f vo O 

S SSi^^^r^ rovjjHVnvoooO ONCocoHH'^Jro oojr-UT.-^ rr-vovn. 
4r-— aov-o M3U)0 HVjJ-(r-roo3 roj:-vnoNrot-cx>\OMDM3UJ on£'U>va 
























o 




'TJ 


o 


& 


s 


* 




1-3 


O S! 




O 


o o 




•i 


J ;:> 


a* 


O 


tJ 1 




CO 








1-3 




n 


O 


^T3 


d- 


o 


H 


P 




c: 


H 




en 



H *^ t?j^ 



JU Hj O -— 
d- CD c+ CO 
H. & SU --_ 

O • H 



1-3 



S)i-3 t?d 



^ 



Hj 



<J CO Q 
9> C 4 '-^ 
H 4 O TO 

gT3 to --^ 
H CO 



CO 

c+ 

O 

t3 



O 

H tr 
H 



<:5 CO 2;>-> 
p C CD H 

^^^^ 
CD H 



g 



1-3 

g- 

W 
H 





4 
CD 

33 



Q 

O 

CO 
CO 



I" 
§. 

CD 
d- 

CO 



H 



H 
O 

I— V 

T 

H 



257 



to to 

o yD 00 ^ O) on l^ .oi co M o o cc -<2 en oi it^- « M 



en u; Ol cji c;iih-« 

ro CO w M OCD 

H CT O M i^iN 

^ -C? O fo MO 

1?^ W H* 03 OC71 



f-'OtOCC-J OJCJl il^MCOHO COC0->3 



ll^ 


M 51 M 


W W M W 


i-" H H 


H H 


M HH 


M H 


t-- 




H 


M 


H M i-J 


o 


03 ^ CXi 


H 0?!-' M 


CX! 00 <o 


03 -CZ 


cn WH 


MRJ 


H CO 


cx)Oi cr> 


O 


Ol 


cn Ol w 


H 


Cji cn 1-J 


M H<3 -vf 


O Ol t}^ 


-v3 W 


N CO -3 


l^•M 


CI -<I 


coo Ol 


-<! 


H 


CO 00 •<! 


rvi 


03 CO 00 


M cn ^ 01 


en «3 ,^ 


CO 03 


H CnH 


CM JO 


Ul CTi 


I> 


M 


03 CO M 


^ 


CJl -0 CO 


1^ -^ -nI CTi 


-3 -vj -C! 


cn H 


M it- CD 


WH 


■<i -C! 


Oi-<j en 


<! 


Ol 


Ul M M 



■■< 


h3 


O 


p) 


!« 


c' 


»i 


i-j 




CD 




'T 




15 



Ol -'I -^J on 00^ -<i^ODCO-v!<i-<2CncOCOCOCOenUir;icoc»jCoCOH(-' MWC-ICOCO 

CO M >> CO &3-0 M !{:>■ Q ^ Ckl W C-J M M CD 00 C>3 CO O W ^^ M « H a W to M M O CO <» 

Cn M Cn M 0<I H ^1 <T^ f'^ I'J '■'3 ifc^ i"'"" W CO C^ '"J <7> en M CD ^3 H 'Si H it^ DJ CO C-1 Cn CD C-: !P- 

Ol W O CO OC;3 OlCJcbcnMCTiOHOO CD i^- COC0^-'-C!I^lP>■O CDOl->3HCnOOlOOO 



en 01 cn oi C7i cn 

03 cn o H CO Oi 

H CD ijs y -o H 

03 Q cn iv 03 -a 

CD #: H SJ CO 00 



ifi. ,t^ ^ ,^ M 03 03 W W M CO CO M ftJ H H M H 
->30101i!^CD01cOCD-N3CDCOC3ir--OCn>^.C>301 
WcO-<!cOCniNHOW OliW t-J fJ 03 M CO ->3 O 
iP-OlOiMOiOl-'COcO CO CD M O -<! O H Ol CkI 

03 0ienwa3M<!->30icnHaiocoJ-'03cni-' 



1 f ^j I, J 

&3 H cooi cn CO 

-<! CO cn (J) OT O 

cn 03 i>-M cn -vi 

cn c^l 03 CO CO < 



H CO !-' M 

->3 O 00 Ol 

cn o 00 cn 

O to CO -v2 

o cn 03 I-J 



H H H' M !-'(-' HMHHHCl-'HCO H H COHMOOOOOOOOOOOOOO f^ 
(-"HCO CO ^3 OHCOCOrJ-<iOOlOc00303-<3 03aiCn03niCr. 
UJHCO03-<I03 CDCnCOCDCnCOMib.-v!-0-C!l>H'OCn,ti>COlP- 



„. iJUi^b.OlOqK-'HCOOCO 
-vl if^ -Cf cn CD -.2 CO CO ifi. 00 



^-'Hl-'r-'M^-'Hi-'K^-'HHHH^-'HHI-'Hl-'^JC0O3C0^0 03O3O3l^en^^C0C0CO 



IW CO ^5 M Ml-' HnHMHCOCOHH MiH HCOrf^OOl-JOlCO 

03 o o CO COCO 00 rfi (>■ cn 00 CO o cn " _ _ .. _ 



OH'cocnHOit^cotn 

>C0t0OOCV5Cnc003CD,^OC0CnOCncD' ■ ' 



(^ Ol CD 



i_j y^ t — t 



vv V.V CO i.\j ij\j f — '■ t — » r-^ •"" t ~ I — 1 — ' \\J r~^ t- v-* N-> ^> v^" 

C00303^f^C^lcO^J•>3 03COOCnOC330ql^MCOCn03l>H-^30^^-^2-^3 
00l-'cOC0-<!CnH-<3Cnl-'CDC0i^OlCnCni-'00OHCOI-'i>i>-<3MO5C0 

---- - -■-•---(SicnooooiOH-' 



!-• K' !■-■ !-• :-••,-' 

03 03 1^ iP^ cnco 
en 03 Cn en OH 
coc>3 0co-^303cncncoo^l-'|^.c•^oa^^f^aJl-»cncocbo3co^l-'cr>CT)OD 



cn 01 Ol cn (N,fc. 

00 --3 H CO CD CD 

CD H Ol C^ CD03 

cn H CD c-3 00 en 

O CD -C? riD f-n rn 



(t' 03 03 03 03 03 03 M CO W CO CO H H M H I-J H (-■ 



\-> i-* i-' y-> i-' 



i--'cocooo63COit^6ciotoC)3 0cocni£>.cocj03»-'cDCDit>.cnocnco-«atF^ 

MC003C0030C/lcD03COHCECOCnOHOO(T. ^Miti-ifa.OOH'CnCJ 

oocnoiHooi{i-cnco-J03cnoc>3-vjit>ocrit^-acDcoco(-Jcn!-'H03oo-v! 

e-n rr> -.*» K^ pa .N, C^l — "^ ^^ /v> /— \ r^ r*-» .K. r\\ /~^ r^i r<n f£> Q^ i«j qa m *».i Q .f«. q} -^T ^Tj 



W M M CO CO CO 

00 <i cn .> CO o 

W O 03 CD cncD 

0-' 03 CO CO tfi^ to 

03 CO (-■ CJ^ OH' 



HMHl-'HI-'HM 

tDco-Cf{T5ifc.03Coooo-v!enc7icncncn 



!^ 



1?^ IP^ l> if^ (t^ (f^ it^ 1^ 



cn cn cn cji 

H ^5 CO CO 
CnCOOOCO-^3c003CO^^i•Hl^^-'OC»00|^-^2C»0^^-'!^OCS003C■0-^30 

-«30cocniti.cooo3i-'Oco->z<.'ot-'CDcrcoHcocno30ii>.030t-'cni-' 



copcos!o^cncncncjiMtpc2g>roMcpcgcpoijti:MMCJ}i£ 



03 03 CO CO cow 

cn o cn ->2 -^5co 

o o to i(^ ^o ir> 

CO ^ -3 H it- -J 

-<3 CO cn M cn •^ 



tOCOCOtOI-'l-'COH'l-'HHI-JI-'M HMH 

l-'OH^-'oooo^J03COI^enl?i.coocD•<i^iloos3o^03 cnocoMco 

tOCD03CnCni|:>.CnCOCN(X)l-'OCn-OCOSOr-'Ht-'03->3COOOiti.003H^Cn 
OcDCDH<»03COOnMCDCOCnil5-H'CDGOHOOO-OCi3COHOCJ>Oi^ 
OCOCDCOCOC;iCOCnfOCOtO->3CncO-C!OOCnCOI-'C>JOOTI-'03Cnh-»-<3 



T5 



o 

o 



258 



CD 



t-> f-i *-> 

CD to «3 

&3 H ^ O 

-Oa>C;l^^MWH'OU^CD-^10>O^^^^MtOHOtOOO-^3010^tN&I^3^->0 



MnMOOMCDCOMOtO-O 



lt^^K^Ol^l-'-^a^3lf!.a)rf>.l^Ol^l-»O^Moocol>-^3,^coocI>oc»cnwH 
o>o^^f^MCJ^MOto^5^-'c»oo«JOl^3MM^Ol^«o-c-3a»H^-»wc^.!i 

l-'00CX)MI-<OH't?^CncX)MM01Mc0t0(-'C0(>CnOH'MOOT«)Ot0 



1^ t— I 1— J I J |«J 1^ UmE |_I UJ Lm» UJ 

jo;^b^Mi^S(^-'McnMCO^^ooa)a)S2a>(:ncno^lli•CT>OlI^■lf>■(^■(MW^} 
c^^wa)CJlc;^^^«D^^o>ool^«oOMMMa>HOOlooo1^-'oo&30>Hlti.to 

C7>H0^301ChlN 03COCDC00001010Cft-<3-<J«3h5MWCOCn-vlCI^OiP>M 



CO CO Co H' t^ t*' H' H' I*' 

j-'Ocv}<oo3CoMO(^.tocriCDCT>osaioo-<io^-a->iai^-oo5 oylCJlCJl^^ 

CO«3l-'0-Cli>OOOtOSI&3-ClpOCOOitOHMCnO-<3cDOa>OlO»-» 
Om«OtOMMOO-C!OtOOi^iP»M«003CDM«OiP>.COM&50if>.tOM 




i>iJ ImA UJ L^ LbI L«1 L_J l_t l-J 

a>C3^G>Oll^■c^lCOHioo^•-3cnc^OlO^Ol^^>.01t;^Ol^^IP>. 

,fv .K. ^n h* .K, or\ .K rn *^n ^ .n .n i-j »x ...s .iv /v\ t-j k« n% .K. ^.^ 

l{s6iMO?^-a&aw<»toc5diWMM^c;i^coSiScoMobi-'Moo<i 



■rP^ 1+^ l[^ t> 
7^% t<^ 1_J 1_J 



^ M CiJ 



^.o^D^D^bcbtJo6^o^c^l^-'to-^301010lc;l0^0^0^t^CJ10lW^^■^•l^■ 

t{i-O100.'-'OOMOlC0H'O-aC0C0-'3C0-<3O5iP'iFiCniP>iP»a)CDH 



en o» 



co£ocoM^3^J^-•l-'Co^-'^-'^-'H 

coco£oooMo>o>Ma>oiMOoooo3oo->3-<jo>oicncr>c3Jc;itjioiif^il5. 

^-»o^-»-^IH^-'OD0^05Co<oaiOlt^oo^Hl^c;^ooa3cno^Hl^tJ^^-•^&I 

a^^-•cnc^IWC^&3Woo^D«Ol^-^Jl-'^-»<£)C^JO>M^oCT)Oo-^^Mc;l■<lMt;1Co 

c>lcooocnol•<ilJ».CJlc^^MowM!^ol-'^^ol^oMSlo-a•^3«)o^-'^-»«J 



COCOCOCOCOM HMtOMMHH 
eOCOCOOOi-'O^OiWCSOlCOOGJCDCOCn-CI^GICnOicncnCJlOIOIi^!^ 

i-»ot-'^HHa>MajR3«oo50i*>oo^HrfS'Oia)a)cocnMif=>aiH»-vic>i 

-^^-'o^c^>MCJ1Clac^I-^3o^ool^.-oMO^oMoocotool-^J-a 

cx)Ml{i.|-»H&^o^^«3o^01C>M&q«)OH01 



.« ^ „ ^ . oi oi M cr. M 

•-"Wcncoajoootoooo 



a 









o 

o 
p 

03 



t 



o 






n »< 4 H, 



O ■< P 

P3 pj 4 
d 4 O -^ 

H- H^ Bi cm 

cf fS D3 — • 



^ 



CD 



H- ^^ (3*1 



o 
I 






bd 
i 
<5 



O 

CD 
< 

<n 
I 

o 

ro 
•d 



to 

O 
! 

M 

to 

00 



H 

H- 

O 

o 
o 

4 
•i 
O 

o 



259 



l-> 














(-» 


to 














^/\ 


(T> 
















O 


CO 


00 


-d 


O) tr. 


#• 


M ^3 


M O 



t-' M HN 

to to <£» (D 

tDCD-<10>OIl^>(J3MHO«)00<0501l|^MW»-'Ot04 




-CI O M 

.. -vj ^3 oi 

^ (_. O M 
CJl CO r-5 W 



g 



w to ^3 M M M 

00 <» 00 c; w to 

Ckj oi ^3 o -o 05 

M ipw to M l-» O 



-c:s-»oo■vl*>oo^!5.oooto-^^o^c^lO«>lo^30o^■^3cna^-<ao^o 

-<30C;i-v300lW-JMCD*wOO-N!itktOOJCJlOOC>3a3mCiCl-vl05->3 
C^I&3a)M011-•OOOCD^3(P.^003CD<a5tp>.^;l^;=.0^0&^01«3CO-v! 



ImI i^ I » 1^ L^ UJ 

COCOI-'HJ-'0©tOtDOOO>CnO>mMtOW&3if^MHMl-«l-'M h-*HM 

tnCOMit^CNCOOnit^MiP'-vfCBOO-JOIOlOIMOIil^WOWf-'-vlOlif^Oll-'OO 

^;^cn^ooo^-'^^o«D05^cn^-'-<3«lo^Oll?'toal^-"HOlo^MCOlf>.Mooc^Ilt^o>^D 

CJic0-v3-v!O->It0OiF='->aft3^OcnMUlHsP»t0OUlWM«3iP>000lO0>-vl-<JC;i 



OOtOOO^O^o^D«)^OOD^OO■^3•<lO>OiCJllt'WMW^5M^3^3^)^-•^^tOMC^J 
COCn«)mM->3M03i!i'JOOOl00^1-»0^tP'->JOlCJltO->3a)H-<Ii|;»WtOO-<IM{0 

coo}CiOI?»MO^^a)^-'^fiOcno^OJ-^^-^a^-•^-'CJll^:wc^l^-<l^•-^JHc;lCDOl^{^o>^5 

005|p'Ov|s.00101tOi|vif=.C;i05-Cia)-<aCiOM03M»-'iI^«)OlMWt->ifi.M01tO 




M H 



M H 



l-» O to 03 to o w 
M O Ol il^ ftj to M 
to to --3 ->3 !> I-J M 



CjM 
H 



5 




M Ol « « C 



tjj CO »-• H i-* »-• !-• 
i^MtOOlO163C0tD00 



CM »/ OJ tW CO ^- . 

^3t-*ooalMl^^-•toolal63cotDoo>3■^3too5-^3010^cr><Iooto 

OOfJtOt-JCn&Jifk0050001WMI-»tOt001tOOtOOOCi3lOWM 



oo^ootD^ococacD<l030lcncnll^^^'0^o^c^lw^3^-'l-'JO}-=^-'^->^-'^-»^-9!-»^3 

-J»^'tNO-<3HM00M-v(01C0W-<a00-<3HOt0a3OCX)CTJO-<I0l6JOl-"tHt00J 

._ . "'■""OOMCDMHMOO-a^lOcnMCnroCOtO-OOCTlOOOI-'if'H' 

(^■Cr. C. t-»C. vOGlCnCCsO tIlil»Mi-»63t0t-<'CJlOC0O(D^01 

O00t0it!.M>IMt0OMO01(j3^W-a0i01-Nirfi.t0MMHOs 



A3 W 00 CO SI H Ol 
00 SI O CO O &3 03 
00 CO 00 01 u o u 



a> 



0»J 



h3 






o 
o 



p' 



G2 
4 

o 

m 

m 

% 

<* 

< 

© 
r 
o 

ct- 

!» 



to 

CO 
to 
I 

M 

to 
o 



260 



Table BeVII. (continued) Variable Capital, 1929-1960 





(g) 
Gross 




Tax Eate 




Total 


(h) 




Eff. 


IDotal 


3ff. 


Net 




Variable 


Fed. 


Fed. 


Tax 


Tax 


Vsjiable 


year 


CaiDital 


Inc. 


Ratio 


Eate 


Paid 


Capital 


1929 


2S156 


.01 


2.09 


.0002 


5 


23151 


1950 


19471 


,01 


2.21 


.0002 


4 


19467 


1 


15182 


.01 


3.06 


.0003 


5 


15177 


2 


11002 


.05 


4.40 


.0022 


24 


10978 


15 


10829 


.04 


3.09 


.0012 


13 


10816 


A 


13604 


.03 


2.68 


.0008 


11 


13593 




15067 




2.28 


.0009 


14 


15053 


6 


17715 


.05 


2.00 


.0010 


18 


17697 


7 


20996 


.06 


1.70 


.0010 


21 


20975 


8 


16837 


.12 


1.75 


,0021 


35 


16802 


9 


18215 


:io 


1.98 


.0020 


36 


18179 


1940 


20637 


.23 


1.91 


.0044 


91 


20546 


1 


28343 


1.25 


1.63 


.0206 


583 


27760 


2 


39655 


3.58 


1.28 


.0459 


1819 


37836 


3 


50000 


6.64 


1.08 


.0717 


3587 


46413 


A 


51763 


6.58 


1.08 


.0711 


3678 


48085 


5 


47700 


6.37 


1.08 


.0686 


3272 


44428 


6 


48859 


5.25 


1.09 


.0573 


2799 


46060 


7 


57163 


5.99 


1.09 


.0654 


3741 


53422 


8 


62197 


4.49 


1.11 


.0500 


3107 


59090 


9 


58162 


4.37 


1.15 


.0504 


2930 


55232 


1950 


65814 


5.03 


1.14 


^0576 


3790 


62024 


1 


77369 


6.49 


1.11 


.0721 


5582 


71787 


2 


82068 


7.29 


1.10 


.0804 


6595 


75473 


S 


88640 


7.51 


1.11 




7362 


81278 


4 


83533 


6.75 


1.13 


.0763 


6370 


77163 


5 


91120 


6.95 


1.13 


.0788 


7182 


83938 


6 


9770S 


7.73 


1.14 


.0879 


8587 


S9116 


7 


100225 


7.76 


1.14 


.0885 


3880 


91345 


8 


94808 


7.55 


1.16 


.0872 


8270 


86538 


9 


104275 


8.21 


1.16 


.0952 


8823 


94350 


1960 


1072&8 


7=85 


1.17 


.0916 


9829 


97459 



■«* 



261 



APPENDIX C 
TABLES SUPPLEMENTARY TO CHAPTER VII 



Note: Sources for these Tables are described in. the 
section of Chapter VI on Sources and Methods . 



262 



to ^ 



I$-MHOitP>'tDOic>qcoiOit.cr>MCDOwaiiP>wo 



JO CO CO w M coco CO 

- ^ O MH O 

-v2 l-»tO -J 









H 


^ 












to 


ro 












O 


135 






i> w 


WM 


o 


*i 














to 


Ui 


> 


CO 


CO 


HM 


H 


c^ 


a> 


CiJ 


o 


O 


to CD 


CD 


O 


*i 


<i 


tn 


i-> 


-dOD 


H 


> 


< 


• 



Lji-.i-jHMCOHHCOCOCOWCOHMHHt-'MMI-' 

-<i->3iotoa5c;icoc»30>>i>' 



MMCl'?^COMSrfici>M~3a>-<!CX)Mlf=>f>£^SS7a WOl 00 

055CTil^-oS-viuicnMOoo>3Hi?.c<ic;ioo-<iiooicnco,p. 



b-' i-' }-> I-' H 

H^ tn oi (?=>■ w 

Ol to CJl H 01 

-<! cr> o en H 

01 t-J Oi -xj M 



^ 



ScCC5C>WWf^tp&3 00pHH20COO.j^OO;^CO;s,Ojj^!^j^C3 

to CD !-' O M 



<^S55wi^McnPcni^toc;iHCocDcoc»p>oiOcjiCD 

MH^MCOO>-J01tF'H'CO-<30a3if=.C.3HOltOaiCnMCR-<l 



^'^SioSrolblMMMCOWHOOOOOtDtOCDOOCD-sJCnCJUiOlUl 
*.HOOCO^^■Hl^l^^^O^O&^OiCO->JO-<3tOOCOHCnHtO^JlCOtnCOH 



MOJMMMMCOWCOCOfOCOCOWWMWW^^ 



00 

03 . 

to c;i 



_ ^- - W W CO CO CO CO 1-; M M H 

HitiGtOOOOH05il^CritOMOC>COCOtnMO>COHtoaiC3W<pO->3 

Si^oii^i-'&q-aoD003CO«)Coo3-<it-'i>cno3Mcrj<&i 



- CO 

it>. Ul 05 W 



HCOWCOtOCOHl-'COCOCOCO 
tO(-'COMCOG5->300MHC71Ul 
tOit^COCOOtOtOCiltD^COCD 
C0<!t0&30-<JOO->I--3COH 



COCOCOCOCOCOCOtOHCOHMMMMHH 

J&Hcooica&JSOMCoHCooD-a-ocnu^M 

i^tOO&^tOCOCnCi5COOtO->IOI-'MO->J 
tOHCTiCpaCiJH'C.Jl-'OIOOCOMH'Mi^-O^ 



MMMWCOMCOI-'HMH 
MCOHOOOlOQCOODOl'-JOi 
aJOOOIUl-J^-sIWWCD,. 
OtO-OOlO^OHUlH-'COCOUIi^tOCn 



l_ii_ii_iHCO COCOCOCOCOCOCO'-OCOCOCOMH 

OlCOOl^COCOH'CJlODOCDCr. OOtOW-Nii^ 
" - - - ^ CJ^ O M CO O Ol !>■ CO O 03 O CO CD 



^•5-3o5H^KJCou3CJ05toooo&3Nc;ic;i^wejtoMHO-<to2W^ 
ScsstySgggwggogNMgMO^MQgggl^toggai 






^3 

p 
p 
o 



i 



en 
<1 



o 

o 



^ 

«* 

g. 



cnj 



►a. 

& 

H 

CD 

o 
I 

M 



I 

o 



o 
^^ 

H 

d 

a 

c+ 

*) 

(D 

ir- 
?> 
a- 
c 



to 
o 
o 
I 

H 

to 
o 



o 

p 

o 

p 
I 

o 



263 



1-" 
to 

05 



to 

en 



to 



05 CD tf^ 

otooo-<i aiO)^cAi^i-'0'j3CD-<Civ^<t^vi!^\-'0^cD^cy>aiif^<ji 



M H 
«D to 

^3 H O to 



WW WW MMwwwwww^3wwwwww Ht-JMWwwww www w w 
oiaiit>>050>oi>^Cncjii^-03Wi&.wwHWOOG2a}a)OaiOMOMOMiP'0> 
toM^>^wc;lOl<li^->3->3ooMOu^-cIOlWl>cococ^IC!5^^i?^-^^c;^al^ti.coc;1WW 



WWWWMWWMWWWWW 
w-aaiita-MH-^icx) oitf^Moi&q 
wwi^-->aip>.woo-<2 -aMWHOi 



!-' W M Cy 03 W W 
Ol en CO ^^ CJl to M 



en en CD to O (-J w 

to Ol M O to O 03 
to t^- 



HHMMH'l-'HI-'l-'Hl-'W 
•nI05«00-v3i^WWH(W->30 



C750tOOlW->2WOl{\3tOW-Nl 
.. _ __^01-'H'Mt-'->3-C!COOtOCJlO> 
OlOlW-sJtOO^HOWCnWMWif'SJt-'Ol 



4 



a> 

o 
i 



cs 

o 

o 



ili. ,Ii Ji. ifi ,f». ,|i. if» CJl CJI ai v> en CJl Ul 05 C^ en 05 Ol i;^ 1^ M W I- ft- W M M W ili' Ol cr. 
l-'WH'0>00-<1010 0WtDO->3tOOrf^(^'OM-<!HtO-acrMtOtO-C!->3Cnaiit. 
C0MU10lO-<!t0ai-viWWCJlOi>MHOt0W01i^CnMrSi;i-0>MU10DMM0^ 
t000 05WOtOMHtt^H'a)tOMWWW-<IWO-<!OtOOlW03CO(lP-x3HMv(i-l-' 




^ 



HtOOt003CnOD->I-JCnOi-<3<IO^^CD01WOO^CJ>HtOCnMt-'Hif»-^tD 
M00HO-afrl-<!l-'WHM(-'tnMl-'H051-'00CD;0Ot0WWaiC0WOaitDt0 
>.-<(, ti.WM-<IMW0500-Nj->aOi>tJOMM0>l-'00OCX)H00Mt?i.i>i;^^Ul01 



(-■HH'MI-JMI-'l-'H'HI-'HH'HHHMHHI-'H'i-'f-'MJ-'t-'HHHI-'t-'M 
OOOWC>IMMl^•l^•0^0^^^•->3•vIOlOla3-^3•>30^lf>•W^-'01l^'WWt-•0(>l-^30 
W0500tOUltOMHtO-vliF'-JUlMif>CnW01Mt0005aDtOOOi>.M05(^iP>.i|^03 
,ti.^-l^0^t^01tOll='^HtD^^m(>l^{i•0>->3-^3CO■^3C^^01050tO^-'tO-^3«tDCn-^3 



1^1 




r? 



,f» rfi. tfi. Jb. iti. i^i. il^ i> t^ i|i. (>. iP. ip. Ol Ul !^ M M W W MM 

. i>05CJi«-'3a>c5WOoioiMuiH'wo5aiocDuiwo- .. -.. . 

osjOMfeSMWt-'toasooo'. cnwcn&JC5->34s--v!cncnifiyiifc.ci5CJ!&30i 



rfi. ifi. (fi lf» ifi (f^ 
Q W O 



W W W W W M M 
01 it^ M W ->J W CO 



264 



B3 



H 



CD -nIO>W>1^MMH' Ot003-viC>0iiH>CNr0 r-=C vDCD^CDtJlrf^MMH 



O 
O 



l-'HH'OOOOO OOOtDtDtOtOtDCO O300 pO0000->3-a;O;O-;3^ -J 

mMSffiCT^MMi-' (^■i>.cnoiF>-<£»tno-<i HO -<i^aD(0-Jcnaih-(Xioo 
^owwSowb S^MoiHH'oa>tpooaiaioi<go,^.WHj<£-ato 

^ W O M O W t^W t£)^$-C^lO^t0•<iHC0l^C^II-'O^0l^004^CJ^^-<l^CJlO 
CnOOOiifirfi.if'.OlOll-'Hi^OlOlO^f^CJllO-'JCJlO^IMWMOlWWCn 



M 03 M M M M MM MMMMWWOJWWMMWWCOHHHMHMH 
COOlWOJvl^MMH tOCn-OMOlMGJWWWOMHOlOroOOOOCOCBOO 
OMCDOBtOMCOCJI -NlC0O)iP--<IMCnuiWM0a-JM<OtpH'i>W-aMW 



.tkMMm!\btba^wo-NJOiWM-JW«30C7i(iiC> oayDWWOioiOtpo] 

OOlWOcrlMWHMtO«3a5^-»CCC3-^D«&3C^CDHI-'Hal^^U^Ol.^O 



S K IS S 15^ ^ MM EElts.M^5l-■r-'HHMOOOO^0«0«>U^'P^0lD 

a>Qlc5-OC001010> M'NlWj^MWt-'CTiloaitDOll-'mCDCOOroCDCV.M 
COf^O^OMO^WCT)Ol(»tDMCOWO^«3(^i^t-'i>-Ct>M;^jOCntOCKi^ 
OlW-NlCOUI-OOW c£i-J-vlCOCT>tOI-iW--3l-'i^OOMOlOOOOlCDtDM 

••• •••••••*•••••• vt^'.t^!-.!^!^ 

C;lM0Dl^•^J■>3-<I0>rfi■MM*'H•NlCJ^MCCC;^C0M•^300l^O^O00O5CJ^ 



W^M.Soro-300:OtoC;l^DC;^^?HOCOCOC^^*;MOCD■gcnO^|^M 
oiSMH^OOr^^ JKoi-^ai^Mt>01tOCJ150COMa)W&3030iHWtO 
OlOi^^OlMCOMC0 j(i.CJlOtOS(CaHOOMt-J-v!Mi^-it»i^OOlMHiF» 



i_ii_iHH!-'H(-JH ^-'^-'^-'^5Co^3Coco£o^.'>coco^5^)MMMMMMM 

• ••••••• »•••»•••••••••••••••• 

m,>^SoaiHOCoaiJ'.f'00-JM-<!-JMMCOtOtOHMMMMi>MCD 



HHHHH-'H'f-'Hh-'HHCOWtOMJOMMWC^KWMMMMMMM 
Ci O) Cn Ol C^ OT O) Ol W m OT H Ol '^ ^ OT ^ jo lo M H <0 H 
MwSSijWW-^ SooOMMHMWOia5ai-<>^0)-JMMCD«DW2 



pj 
4 






o 



H 

o o 

o <+ 

Hj P 
M 



o 
ca 



o 

o 

o 

01 P 

g td <r. 
B H- p* 

d- P 
H- H 

o 
p 



O O tH 
o- O O 

p I 



nj 




w 




H 




CD 




H- 




o 




f) 




.t* 




© 


o 


y 


.*->. 


1 


H> 


>i 


H> 


M 




O 


s-^ 


pJ 




o 








^ 


, 



H3 



O 
J 
M 



'O 

ct 

P 
M 

O 

o 



o 

p 

^d 

w 

e*- 
P 
H 

O 

O 

a 



O 



It" 



o 

o 
p 

c»- 
CD 
P 
d- 

O 

Hj 

cl- 
P" 

O 

o 

CD 

a 
o 



O 

o 

! 

H 

CD 
O 



265 



CO 

cn 



H" 










(-> 


«o 










to 


O UD CO <! 


cn 


Ol 


^^ 03 


CO M 


{^ 



to 03 ^ a>ai if^M w H-* 



M H l-J M M H 

i}i ,>. (^ M N CO 

M H O •>a COCO 

CO M M if:» CXItD 

M 00 Ol -O if I-" 

to ->3 M M iP--^! 

• • • • • • 

Ol Ol ^ H* toco 



l-'HHHh-'H'H'H 
WCOHMMMOO 
a> M to CT> CO O O) H 
MM^COtOHCnW 
C0OlC0O>C»3C^tO^3 



tOtOtOtDtOOtOtDOO 

cnMit'Cntooto^OHCO 

SICOOtP>'t!^Hif»tOOi-<3 
J-'tOHOOMCJlif'-^lCJlH-'- 

" • Ol cyi -d -v! ^^ 



t-J H M M H H 

O O O M H H 

03 l^• <i O M O" 

l-J cr> M ifi- O CT) 



CD^-l^-'a5C^I-^3C^IO^CJl^-'l^^O^-' 
OtOCOODWOi03<OWi!i-OW O00->3C;)O 



b 00 1^ JO M (-» 
Ol Ol M M 00 



to to 

M CO 
O to 



■<l Ol 

01 Ol 

O CO 



->3to(>iyioDoai ^-<i 






<D 

I 



o 

o 
3 



3omcomS-3cSSmCTSi>aiH-Ja:OMcOOiC7iOlC^OiOlOiWOJqh-M 

£MS§MMS^^P-aMtO-OaiOiaiM&3 000-^3CO-OOlWM.^WtD5^W 
{:; S W C^ MO S Oi S O 5 M W H O H a- r- p f-^ W p Ul -3 ;a W p j> ,f^ O M W 

03 H to b b «D 03 00 Ol Ol b b Ol *0 to M M CD *tO *-v! O H « "tO <! O Ol M Ol Ol Ol -3 



ro!^!^!^!^KolO^WO^rf^^^MW£OWMMCOWCOCOCOCOMM.>l^.^.^^ 
OmmSMal^il'COtDJ-.•-n.^O<!C^)0^5-^20tOOlOl-^^tOcOOM!t^ql-^. 

OOOlCOCJlClH CiOlCi-* 



ooih.o^oioco'^SSoio'i^toJodMlt^oi-jcora 

(ScOOtOMOO-<ICD->3M<IUl^pCnMtD^O*^ 



M § ^ S -J S Ol -^ O W ro O p p p CO O O p M -3 M W CT O M -3 Ol ^-<I t^ 

*rfi b en M to ^ m *-ci cc M w Ol t^ H H Ol H *co b Ol ^ o^ M b b M o to Ol H w .> 



H W W M HM 

CO CO CO CO HH 



(_i (_1 (_. H" , ^ 

|-'l-'OOOcOtDCI)--3->3 
r^Mi>MC»4^COOa3CJlO^CO&3gip 
WOICOOCOCO Ol030iCO(>MCOtOCOgi 
-JOMMOlM OlH'l-'ODOlCTlt-'OtOC'J 



-5 -<3 00 -^ -nJ ^/ 

&q to O CD Ol -0 

CO CO <! O CO to 

Ol CO 03 CD Ol O Ol 03 



-.3-a-ci-«-3a>cocr>CD 
-ooiit^oiascooigo-^ 

tOoaCOCOCOHcOOH' 
O (71 03 H -V3 03 CO 



b'uibb^boOH03tDCOt-'Oia)tDC.30D.P^H-3lO<U10lO-atOOllOCO&3 




Ol O: 00 to 

S.l§isSSSS5^?io;SoiwSM;^oa;^coPb5«coHi!.6i^b 



(-il-'H'l-'f-'Ml-'t-'HMMI-'HHCOCOtO HCOCOCOCOCOHHM 

b b b b b b b b b b M M M H b J^ 1^ en b CO *o b b b b b g w H b b b 

OC00301-<!tDOI-'C0;Pl-'C0f-'00OOC;iMg00}-'MOOlM0lO&qWOgW 
mHM^-'tD0lOOOH'CO-CZ<i£O-^3OO■<!CDOC^ICOCOO^^Cn•-«OCOOH^^W 
M^OOl^OOH^-O^h-^CSOWOl^OlSJCOOlClOOl^OlCOMOlHCOt^ 



Hj - 



266 



APPENDIX D 
TABIES SUPPIEIvEWTARY TO CHAPTER VIII 



267 



Table D«I Producti'sity and Wage Indexes 

(1929 a» 100) 





(a) 


(b) 


(c) 




Labor 


Hourly 


Labor 




Net- 


Seal 


Gross- 


year 


Productivity 


wage 


Produetivity 


1900 


72cU 


6U,1 


6ii.5 


1 


70e8 


65,2 


63,a 


2 


TleO 


63.7 


62.5 


3 


72o8 


62.5 


62.9 


h 


71.7 


65.9 


6i».6 


5 


7U.1 


67.6 


65.9 


6 


71.0 


66.5 


6U.2 


7 


69,6 


63.il 


62.2 




u 


73.8 


63.8 


67.7 


9 


73.9 


68.7 


68.3 


1?10 


77.7 


T0.9 


69.2 


1 

X 


7lv.6 


66.9 


6?.li 


2 


68«8 


65.U 


61.8 


3 


77o2 


70.6 


69.6 


U 


75.i(. 


e8.3 


70.6 


5 


79.0 


70,9 


73.1; 


6 


79.2 


72.1j 


70.9 


7 


72*9 


70.1i 


70.U 


8 


68«5 


76,3 


70.9 


9 


7h.h 


82.0 


75.1 


1920 


81«li 


8Ue3 


?6.2 


1 


87o5 


Bl^U 


87.0 


2 


81.5 


88.3 


8U.9 


3 


87.6 


9lio3 


85.9 


fe 


8$vB 


96.3 


91.7 


5 


90a 


92.9 


90.9 


6 


9U*3 


9h.$ 


9it.l 


7 


86o7 


96olt 


91,7 


8 


97.1* 


98.6 


99.lt 


9 


100.0 


100.0 


lOOoO 


1930 


99.9 


101.6 


106.0 


1 


9Si3 


107.3 


118.6 


2 


80.5 


108.5 


120.3 


3 


76.0 


105.7 


110.9 


U 


98*9 


319*2 


125.0 


5 


105.2 


120.2 


125.6 


6 


109.7 


121.3 


121*.2 


7 


115.8 


129.9 


126.3 


8 


120.6 


13U.ii 


Ill9e7 


9 


119.0 


133.1; 


iU7.0 


19U0 


126.2 


138.1 


152.0 



268 



Table D-I (contdnusd) 

gear (a) (b) (c) 



im. 


12lt.8 


138.8 


11j7o3 


2 


i23.i| 


UiOo8 


137.1 


3 


120«5 


139.1; 


131.0 


k 


12U.lj 


lli0.5 


133.0 


5 


12UoU 


lbO.8 


1?in.2 


6 


119,5 


lia.9 


lli3.1 


7 


119.1} 


1U3.9 


ll*3,i» 


6 


13U.2 


150.lt 


155.1 


9 


135«7 


156oli 


165.5 


1950 


139.7 


16U.9 


176,0 




iijl.z 


166,5 


177.7 


2 


lit3.3 


171.1 


181.7 


3 


li|6.2 


177.9 


186,6 


k 


151.6 


183.2 


198,2 


5 


163.2 


189.2 


210.7 


6 


16U.0 


19koh 


215.8 


7 


167.1 


199.2 


227.5 


8 


168.0 


201.7 


238.0 


9 


nk.k 


205.2 


2kh*7 


1960 


178.6 


211,1 


253.7 



Howccest 



(a)s Tabls vn=I 

(b) s Table B-VU, coltann h divided ty tbc product of pries 

index (Table B-I) and total laan-hotirs troriced (Table C=I, 
column h) 

(c) J Tabls D^I^ coltsan h dirldsd by ths product of pricee 

index (Tfliblt B=I) and total man-hours worked (Table C-I. 
column h) 



269 



TABLE S-IJ 



Hates of Increase of ITet-Productivity and Hourly Real V/ages 
i'Jet-Productivity (fo pet annuGi) 



•fco 


issy 


ii?^-U 


J-bbU 


frto 






1905 


1.28 


1.52 


1.60 


1929 




2.12 


1.87 


1940 






1.74 



Eoiirly Eea,l ¥age (^ per annum) 

to 1929 1940 1960 



from 








1905 


1.5S 


2.04 


2.07 


1929 




2.93 


2.41 


1940 






2.12 



b (Elasticity of hourly real v;age v/ith respect to net- 
productivity) 

to 1929 1940 1960 



from 








1905 


1.27 


1.34 


1.29 


1929 




1.39 


1.29 


1940 






1.22 



Source: Tatle D-I 



270 



H 
00->3CnOllt^M^5l-'OfDCD■>30^a^l^ 



GSMl-'O«3C0-<lcnoijf^WMl-' O 



UD CD CO KZ ->J 



M03C^IC^IMMWWC^1^5MW^-'^-'l-'^-'H^-'l-'^-' H yf 

O^I-'MCOSIMCnHl-'l-'CJlOcOO^-tOOOt-'OMCniDi^OlplOlCOW 

Cn^0l^s.M^0MHC0WHt0^J'X)C;^-C!O•^3O-^3OI-'^>-^I«^C^)rfi.-^3^D 



03Mciit>.MMOMc;iocx)tooo->3a><30icr)cr)(;nqioioi03if^t;ii>MM 
tv3i_iMtSa)oowMCO-<Jcn£oc7>?ocr)f-'cowcDii^iii.OiOO>?it-'WCDpa 

tOOOfiDMyJOlOOOIMOlOWOOt-'if^Olt^CDCnMMCTli^-CDOOCnOl 



Ol 01 CJl CJl 01 

-<J <I 01 M H 

0> CO -vj 05 w 

05 O «3 M M 



)-'MHt-'M->300*»OOOtOCDa)-C!0!lT)Cn 
CDCnM£OMMCn05-vJOi0001rf^MI-'l-'i)^-J 
COOJMI-'CDOIfP-l-'OlHMI-'WOlMCS 



l-J )-i 4_J I— I l-J 

i^. M M M CO 

_ en il^ ^ CT) 1^ 

->3 O O 00 CJl rfi' O 



OOH-'l-'aJtO^IOiOCOMMH 

oocntoooiMcntD^otooooai 



,|i. rfi. « CI 03 W 

o 01 -^J o 05 ^5 



(jf-'E^MHI-'HI-'h-'h-'Hl-'l-' 

C0O3B0<!-<3-OO)i{=>-tO->3O5*>.l-'!JDUD!£>000DCDa30D 

«)l-'WCD03MOOOOO<IC001R30)i<i'MCTlCOCD03W 

o^o^c3MH^c;1^^•c^lCotD^f^^-'^3C^>lF^05c;lOo^oo 



00 -<! 



-s3 en CTl OS Oi Ol 

M 00 av tti. O 'O 



G> 01 Oa en Cr. Ul ^^ 1^ en il^ it^ M &3 ^3 W M M W CO r-= H" H ■- H M M t- H M 

OiCOMO^'MinCOCOOW ;DtDW i^eO!-'Ui>-'OlWi>lOOD;^tDCnOjgW 
HCD->3l001l-'Mit>i«3«3Ul05Wa>t;^OtO-vICO'Oh-'<10lO->3ra5jOt-'W 
OOaWMOOitJluiwMOOifil-'^'MOlWl-'MMOOCnHOOmcD 



tO-5o^. Mt£l■>301•^3WG5^^0oa)C;l010^05C^^MCO^^MMMO(^;5ra;:^ 
WOtOWOil^COHOO.t5.Cr>0>-»WM?001(f>-WOOD-<Icr5-<iMt£)00)M 



05cnolOlO)c;^l^l^.a)0^l^c,'CJW^5Cowco^3^3^-'M^-'l-'^-fH^-•H 
cf)Moio^-<3a)03i-'OiP>.^oaiif^cjiWMMOOD003-joi"^y3S5 

a)O)OCTl^3CT»t^^0lM^-'>F>■0D^£)O-viCTl^0CJlOCJ^Cn|-'t0C0O^O00 

coMM ^.■<I05MOc;^^-'^^c^l-^JHi.ali-'0uOl0JOl-'-^I0^wpcnalO 

^JSM01OO-J02t-'0>00O01C^I05MO^03^3^-'■^3a)M^f>•c0OW 



■<! 









P 




4 







teJ 





B 


B *c< 


•d 


M 


fl) 





Kj-kj 


ffl 


(D 


!» 





<:1- 





i 



O 



03 
I 



M =3 
fi OS 



o 
ci- 
ts' 

m ,-> 

o 

w 

0) 



I? 



*1 o 

p. v^ 

O 
4 



H- p O 



>^ K W 
pj CO ro '— 

^ I 



H3 bd n 

p j:: B 

(D K* H" CP! 

03 3 M v_ 

ra 0) 

m o 

01 c*- 



o o 

pJ 03 

pi m 
o 

cl- 



i 



o 

rt- 

03 



ca 
c^ 

C« 

o 

o 

H 

£p 
4 

O 

03 
03 

►tJ 

H 
O 

o 



o 
o 
I 

to 
(?> 
o 



M 
H- 
O 
J3 

O 

o 



4 

tJ 
O 
(-• 
M 

03 

03 



271 






to 



M 
CO 



OtDC0-<ia501i>MMt-'OtO00-305aii^MS0r--OcDC0-<JCncnit^ <j3M 

§SMO?SS^-'^?WWwJ^-a-<3Wa^COl^!-'■i3■<lMO.^y^O^M ^m 
*^M-<^OwStOHOOMWUlOMQ001vOqWHMMWtO -2M 

wOMWMto^il^ocDcDOJcr. oo-«3aiO(p'Mcn-v3i-'MHWO->a wo 



to to 

M O to 



^3 M M 
00 tJi. CD 
Cn CD -J 

<y> w 00 

CD O Ol 



ulylOlOll^l^wMCJc^lMCOMCowwww£OH^-'M^-'HM _.,j. 

O5^O}-»tO-va<:0ara->3WcoNM&5t^Cn!t.O-«3MI-'HWI-'«D-<aM£; 
omOMiNCJlCrtC3'iCnCDO0lCV>->3-vlc0OC0C0MC0C00505t^CM-;^'^CE~~-~- 

WCTSSroM«t2e:^W*>SHcoSo^MMJ:.OltN3.f'0^01^WMO&aOCOC71 



to i^- ^ 

».^ *W «.S 



mfiiMMMoSS!^a^w^MW003-c-o-acncjiOiCJiOi*'.t^*'tferf^c;ioia 

SSiaMS^M§SNMM^-3WMO^H3HOlMI-'H2oOlw5U]MOOO 

HHW0lS^OMW^^3O-^Ia>00C0W-^•^Si'£''^iSo2M^^£S!^ 
MUlcO(>Il-'WCOC;irf^<OMtUCD03COl-'it^if^->3Cn->3vt=>-<l-OOOOH'»-'Ulvwv«T- 



l_-i_Ji_:i_;t_si-!S_!|-JHCOM MM Ml-'!-' 

OOtOCJiaOOOtD^a>-C!OOicOHpCOCOWMO;>3MM 

CD -.3 H O " 
&3 M W M 



imcni£i.OQ-JOCncDt-'OOOCOWMO->3J\3l-' HM ^ ^ tf 

SSroO^SMMi^WwSMUltOtOSMCCMWOOOJ^Ml^OiO 
0^Ma>^5SOlCJlMHpO0^0^-^3S!01Hro-3gOW|^p1^-'H0D0^ 



S^StOMGq{DMWW^OMUlC0C000CDH«a-0-^WC£SS^R?^S 
OlWH^300-^I01WO-^3 0^00CJll-'^3•<I0^3^-'W^>■^f^>3^-'0^-^i^OCDOl 



CO CO H M H 
M O Oi Ol to 
Ul tP- 
M H 



mMHMSo^^<!MSI^^i■M^^aDK^M^0^3cO!-'tOOO^DOqlCO^Op|^000 
0i*.CnO0lC0^Ot0OM00iF>--300OC;i0iHOO-J 



' OJ #► -J *» !?>• 
to O CO M CO w 



M 03 M CO 



MWMMCOCOWWWCO 
^tti-HO00O(Mi>C0 
M H H 03 to 

-o CO CD cn 1^ 
o w CO it^ a> 



0000>Ol^^MCOI-'OtOOD•^J■^3^0^050>qlCil.>0]al01 
t^HHMMi^CJIOOMMMHH'MCOq^HptOOlOcOOjOHi^H 
OTMSHMtOMcOCO-JWCOH-iJO-OOCJlCnMi^Oorooi-JMai 

"^vy^!:3_-^.v«__.. 'DjocoH05CDOo<ioi42>.a>oa5too^oo 



CDOiMOlCOCDH-'OlMyi 



.^COMI-'HMl-'h-'l-'Hl-' 
MCOtOSIOOOlMOJMMl-' 
__ totOSIi>COcOCX)C00500 
C0i>MO00C;i05t0Cll-'t0-0MC0C0C0H(>M 
C^l5^5^^C01-'COM-^!OcD^-'COl^^};^OOffl 
0>->3aD^H't->MW-<3fJCOCOtOOO«OCMa)0 



MMMCiJCOCOC0^3^3 

S030MCO-<1*>.CJ1M„ _ 
cnoieacncocoJp-cotosi 



ODOioitnOJCivf^if^MMCjcnoi 

OO-OCDCJlOif'-'JCOOIOiOCOCO 
OCrJtOcDCOi-'OCJJCDMI-'it^M 
ip. to H" -a CD CO r-' CO CO 03 00 CJl M 
l-'aiOl-v!-0i^--N!00C0c0i0cDO 



Sources: 



■< 
4 



o 
I 



o 

o 

a 
P' 



to 



H5 



}^ 



- Columns (a) through (e): See Chapter VI, section on 
Sources and Methods . 

- Column (g): for I929-I96O, "based on U.S. Income and Output , 
Tahle 1-12 5 for 1900-19?3, hased on Kendrick, Productivity 



Trends in tne u . b . , 



Tahle A-II-B. 



272 



lable D-IV. 


Expand- 


ed (Gross of Taxes 


) Bates of 


Profit and Surplu 


s- 




Value, 


1900-1960 (Millions of Laljor 


-Units) 






(a) 


(b) 


(c) 

Expanded 


(d) 

Expansion 
Of 






s« 


eL 


Surplus- 


Surplus- 




year 






?alue 


Falue 




1900 


74.4 


11.63 


10489 


721 




1 


67.6 


11,45 


10461 


773 




3 


71.9 


12,63 


11749 


788 




S 


79.0 


13.74 


12902 


727 




4 


68o3 


11.81 


11237 


823 




5 


68.7 


12,88 


12352 


841 




6 


64.3 


12.49 


12455 


898 




7 


68.8 


12.95 


13472 


925 




8 


79.3 


12.35 


13095 


866 




9 


66.8 


12.01 


12926 


1026 




1910 


77.6 


13,74 


14843 


930 




1 


72.3 


12,96 


14313 


1015 




2 


62.4 


12.00 


13561 


1066 




3 


68.4 


12.5? 


14426 


991 




4 


70.7 


11.79 


iS3S3 


1007 




5 


72.2 


11.94 


13994 


S52 




6 


69.4 


12.85 


15703 


1209 




7 


82.3 


13.63 


18062 


4278 




8 


65.8 


11.18 


15801 


6156 




S 


55.9 


9.28 


13223 


3976 




1920 


57.4 


10.00 


14000 


2643 




1 


62.1 


8.25 


11438 


1854 




2 


50.6 


7.83 


10932 


2348 




3 


49.6 


8.88 


12485 


2381 




4 


50.8 


8.24 


11764 


2321 




5 


57,0 


9.19 


13194 


2326 




6 


50.8 


9.93 


14324 


2238 




7 


48.3 


8.25 


12253 


2459 




8 


60.0 


9.57 


14062 


2372 




9 


61.3 


9.90 


14GG1 


2??. 2 




1930 


59.2 


8.32 


12408 


2103 




1 


46.9 


5.97 


8806 


2341 




2 


27.5 


3v25 


4730 


2906 




3 


24.6 


3.20 


4618 


3351 




4 


40,8 


5.34 


7133 


2688 




5 


47.2 


6.52 


8489 


2594 




6 


54,4 


8.30 


10738 


3169 




7 


49.2 


8,29 


10744 


3023 




8 


49.9 


6,71 


8584 


2335 




9 


52,0 


7.72 


9728 


2947 




1940 


61.2 


9.29 


11579 


3812 





273 



Table D-IV. 


(continued) 








year 


(a) 


(■b) 


(c) 


(d) 


1941 


72.9 


12.56 


16312 


6899 


2 


59,4 


14.54 


19008 


8626 


3 


68.2 


16.74 


21293 


10077 


4 


65.2 


16.50 


20233 


8348 


5 


63,2 


14.66 


17656 


7153 


6 


54.0 


12.00 


15291 


6894 


•7 


49. S 


10,86 


14868 


6721 


8 


57.0 


11,60 


16363 


5615 


9 


49.3 


9.32 


13488 


4537 


1950 


57.4 


10.58 


15681 


7187 


1 


59.5 


11.13 


17199 


8041 


2 


51.6 


9.86 


15714 


7002 


S 


47.5 


9.39 


15254 


7084 


4 


46.5 


8.36 


13707 


6003 


5 


55.2 


9.78 


16148 


6543 


6 


51.3 


9.17 


15720 


6757 


7 


50.2 


8.48 


14962 


6467 


8 


48.0 


7.47 


13302 


5748 


9 


52.2 


8.37 


14923 


6210 


1960 


50.2 


7.95 


14377 


5923 



274 



Chart D-Io 



Expanded (Gross of Taxes) and Actual 
(Wet of Taxes) Rates of Profit and 
Svirplus -Value p 1900-1960 (Labor- 
Unit Basis) 




275 



Chart D-IIe 



Expanded (Gross of Taxes) and Actual 
(Net of Taxes) Rates of Profit, 
Peacetime Peak Years, 1903-1960 
(Labor-Unit Basis) 




Sr ml - l-oftarlt h mfc 
2(:yclr3x lOtuihcinch 



rt^ fU7 if>i /ta /fti ii0 



v\ 276 



\ 



BIBLIOG-RAPHY 



277 



BIBLIOGRAPHY 

Bortkiewicz, Ladislaus von, "On the Correction of Marx's 
Fundamental Theoretical Construction in the Third 
Volume of C apital ," in Eugen von Bilhm-Bawerk. Karl 
Marx and the Close of his System; and Rudolf 
Hilferding, B^hm-Bawerk's Criticism of Marxo Nev; 
York: Augustus Kelley, 1949 « 

Clark, John Bates, The Distribution of ^lealth, New 
York: Macmillan, 1902 o 

Dickinson, H.D. ''The Palling Rate of Profit in Marxian 
Economics," in Review of Economic Studies ^ February 
1957, i20ffo 

Dobb, Maurice, Political Economy and Capitalism. New 
York; International Publishers, 1940» 

Domar, Evsey, Essays in the Theory of Economic Growth, 
New York: Oxford University Press, 1957. 

Engels, -Priedrich, Herr Eugen Diihring's Revolution in 
Science (Anti-DiJhringo) New York: International 
Publishers, 1939, 

"Outlines of a Critique of Politi'cal Economy," 

°^ irTKarl Marx, Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts 

of 1844, MoscoY/: Foreign Languages Publishing 
House, 1959", 

Gillman, Joseph M, The Palling Rate of Profit, London? 
Dennis Dobgon, 1957* 

Goldsmith. Raymond, A Study of Saving in the United 
States, 3 vols, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton 
University Press, 1955-1956, 

Glisten, Rolf, Die Langfristige Tendenz der Profitrate 
bei Karl Marx und Joan Robinson, Thesis « Munxch, 
1960 

Hegel, G.W.Pc The Logic of Hegel, translated by William 
Vifallace. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1892, 

Hicks, James R, The Theory of Yfages, London: 
Macmillan, 1932. 



278 



Hilferding, Rudolf. B8hm-Bawerk ' s Criticism of Marxo 
New York: Augustus Kelley, 1949, 

Kendrick, John Wo Productivity Trends in the U.S. 

Princeton, N,J,; Princeton University Press ^ 1961© 

Keynes. John Maynard« The General Theory of Employment, 

Interest, and Money. New York? HarcoTxrt Brace, 1935o 

Kuznets, Simon S* National Income and its Composition, 
1919-1938, New York: National Bureau of Econorrdc 
Research, 1941 e 

Lenin, V.Ic' Imperialism, The Highest Stage of Capitalism, 
with New Data for Lenin's Imperialism, New York: 
International Publishers, 1940, 

, "On the So-called Market Question," in Collected 

Works, volo I« Moscow; Foreign Languages Publishing 
House, 1960 o 

Lerner, Abba P<, "Marxism and Economics," in Joxornal of 
Political Economy, March, 1945, 79 ff o 

Malthus, Thomas Rs Principles of Political Economy* 
New York: Augustus Kelley, 1951 » 

Martin, Robert ¥, National Income in the U.S., 1799-1938s 
New York: National Industrial Conference Board, 1939 o 

Marx, Karl. Das Kapital. 3 vols. Wien: Verlag fur 
Literatur und Politik, 1933-1934. 

Capital. 3 vols. Chicago: C. Kerr & Coe, 



1906-1909. 

, Capital, vols. 2 and 3. Moscow: Foreign 

Languages Publishing House, 1957-1959. 

, Critique of Political Economy. New York; 

International Library Publishers, 1904. 

, Grundr-isse der Kritik der Politiscben 6'konomie 

iRohentwurf.) Berlin: Dietz Verlag, 1953, 

. "Theses on Peuerbach, " in Marx and Engels, 

"The German Ideology. New York: International 
Publishers, 1947. 

, Theorien iiber den Mehrwert, 2 vols. Berlin: 
"Dietz Verlag, 1956-1959, 



879 



M&TXp Karl* Theornes of Surplus -Value * Excerpts, edited 
and translated by Emile Burns. New York: Int^j:'- 
national Publishers, 1952 o 

, Value, Price, and Profit. London: G. 43-len 

and Unwin, 1899. 

Marx and Engelso "Manifesto of the Communist Party," in 
Capital and Other Writings. New York: Modern 
Library, 1932. 

» Selected Correspondence. New York: Inter- 
"national Publishers, 1934. 

Mill, John Stuart. Principles of Political Economy^ 
2 vols. New York: Appleton, 1864. 

Naville, Pierre. De L 'Alienation a Xa Jouissance: t,s, 
Genese de la Sociologie du Travail chsz Marx et 
Engels. Paris: Marcel Riviere, 1957. 

Ricardo, David. \¥ork3 and Correspondence of David 
Ricardo. Edited by Piero Sraffao 10 vols. 
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1951. 

Robinson, Joan. The Accumulation of Capital. London: 
Macmillan, 1956 « 

. Economic Philosophy, Chicago: Aldine 
Publishing Co., 1952, 

, An Essay on Marxian Economics. London; 

Macmillan, 1952. 

Rosdolsky, Roman. "Der Gebrauchswert bei Karl Mar:!^,^ 
Eine Krltik der Bisherigen Marx-Interpretaiixon,'- 
Kyklos, XII (1959,) 29 ff. 

"Zur- TTeueren Kritik des Marxschen Geset^es 
der'Eallenden Profitrate," Kyklos, TX (1955.) 



Smith, Adam. The Vifealth of Nations. 3 vols. New York: 
Library of Universal Literatui-e, 1911. 

Sowell, Thomas. "Marx's 'Increasing Misery' Doctrtne," 

American Economic Review, L, no. 1 (March, I960,) 111 ff. 

Strachey, John. Contemporary Capitalism* New Yo]?k: 
Random House, 1955. 



280 



Sweezy, Paul M. The Theory of Capitalist Development. 
New York: Oxford University Press, 194-2. 

Taussig, Krank W, Principles of Economics « 2 vols* 
New York: Macmillan, 1911. 

Terborgh. GeorgOc Realistic Depreciation Policy. 

V/ashington: Machinery and Allied Products Instx-cute, 
1954. 

Sixty Years of Business Capital Formation. 

Wai'hington: Machinery and Allied Products Instiva-oe, 

1960. 

Tucker, C-.L.S. Progress and Profits in British Economic 
Thought, 1650-1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University 
Press, 1960. 

U.S. Bureau of the Census. Census of Manufactures, 1954. 
Washington, lo57, 

, Census of Manufactures, 1958, VJashington, 1961. 

, Census of Mineral Industries, 1958. 

Washington, 1961. 



U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. B.L.S. Bulletin 1312, 
Employment and Earnings. V/ashington, 1961. 

U.S. Department of Commerce. Historical Statistics of 

the U.S., Colonial Times to 1957. \^'ashington, 1958. 

. National Income, 1929-1953. Washington, 1954. 

, Statistical Abstract of the U.S., 1962- 
Washington, 1962, 

, Survey of Current Business (per.) July, 1962. 

« U.S. Income and Output. Washington, 1958. 



U.S. Departments of Labor and Commerce. Construction 
Review (per.)' 1958-1962, 

, Construction Volume and Costs, 1915-1956. 

Washington, 1957. 

U.S. Internal Revenue f Service, Statistics of Income 
(annual.) 1916--19^.